World Bank
- 格式:pdf
- 大小:497.52 KB
- 文档页数:46
世界银行贷款项目工作手册第一章概述一、世界银行简介世界银行(the World Bank)是联合国属下的一个专门机构,负责长期贷款的国际金融机构。
World Bank是根据1944年美国布雷顿森林会议上通过的《国际复兴开发银行协定》成立的,其宗旨是通过对生产事业的投资,资助成员国的复兴和开发工作;通过对贷款的保证或参与贷款及其他和人投资的方式促进外国和人投资,当成员国不能在合理的条件下获得私人资本时,则在适当条件下以银行本身资金或筹集的资金及其它资金给予成员国直接贷款,来补充私人投资的不足;通过鼓励国际投资,开发成员国的生产资源,提供技术咨询和提高生产能力,以促进成员国国际贸易的均衡增长及国际收支状况的改善。
根据世界银行的宗旨,其主要业务活动是,对发展中成员国提供长期贷款对成员国政府或经政府担保的私人企业提供贷款和技术援助,资助他们兴建某些建设周期长,利润率偏低,但又为该国经济和社会发展所必需的建设项目。
世界银行与国际开发协会(International Development Association, IDA)、国际金融公司(International Finance Corporation, IFC)、多边投资担保机构(Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency, MIGA)、国际投资争端解决中心(International Centre for Settlement of Investment Disputes,ICSID)五部分共同组成了世界银行集团(World Bank Group).世行资金来源:世界银行利用国际资本市场筹集发展资金,国际开发协会则依靠较富裕的成员国政府的捐款。
世界银行致力于推进的几个主要方面:体制方面上:完善良性廉洁的政府管理体制、有效的法律和司法制度、良性和受监管的金融系统、社会安全保障制度和社会计划;物质上:解决供水和污水、能源、道路、交通和通信、环境和文化问题;具体战略:针对农村、城市和民营部门。
世界银行(The World Bank)是全球最大的发展援助机构,致力于为成员国提供低息贷款、无息信贷和赠款等资金支持,以促进经济发展、减少贫困和改善民生。
世界银行在实施项目时,通常采用严格的评标方法,确保援助资金的合理分配和有效利用。
世界银行的评标方法主要包括以下几个方面:1. 项目可行性研究:在项目申报阶段,世界银行会对项目进行全面的可行性研究,包括项目的经济、社会、环境等方面。
通过可行性研究,评估项目是否具有投资价值、是否符合世界银行的发展战略和成员国的发展需求。
2. 项目评估:世界银行会对申报的项目进行评估,包括项目的目标、范围、预算、实施计划等方面。
评估的目的是确保项目具有明确的发展目标、合理的预算和实施计划,并确保项目能够在规定的时间内完成。
3. 评标委员会:世界银行会设立评标委员会,负责对申报的项目进行评审。
评标委员会由世界银行的专家和外部专家组成,他们根据项目的实际情况和评估标准,对项目进行独立、公正、客观的评审。
4. 评估标准:世界银行制定了严格的评估标准,包括项目的可持续发展性、效益、影响、风险管理等方面。
评估标准旨在确保项目的有效性和合规性,同时充分考虑项目的环境和社会影响。
5. 评审过程:评标委员会根据评估标准,对申报的项目进行评审,并提出评审意见和建议。
评审过程分为预审、初审和终审三个阶段。
在预审阶段,评标委员会对项目进行初步筛选,确定符合评估标准的项目;在初审阶段,评标委员会对项目进行详细评审,并提出改进意见和建议;在终审阶段,评标委员会根据项目的改进情况,最终确定是否批准项目。
6. 项目批准:经过评标委员会的评审,世界银行会根据评审结果,决定是否批准项目。
对于批准的项目,世界银行会与成员国签订项目协议,并拨付资金支持项目的实施。
7. 项目监督与评估:在项目实施过程中,世界银行会对项目进行监督与评估,确保项目按照协议要求和相关法规进行,确保项目的有效性和合规性。
同时,世界银行还会对项目进行定期评估,以了解项目的进展情况,及时发现问题并采取措施加以解决。
世界银行(WBG)世界银行(WBG)世界银行(WBG)是世界银行集团的俗称,“世界银行”这个名称一直是用于指国际复兴开发银行(IBRD)和国际开发协会(IDA)。
这些机构联合向发展中国家提供低息贷款、无息信贷和赠款。
它是一个国际组织,其一开始的使命是帮助在第二次世界大战中被破坏的国家的重建。
今天它的任务是资助国家克服穷困,各机构在减轻贫困和提高生活水平的使命中发挥独特的作用。
世界银行(World Bank)世界银行(World Bank)成立于1945年12月27日,1946年6月开始营业。
凡是参加世界银行的国家必须首先是国际货币基金组织的会员国。
成立的详细背景参照国际货币基金组织一章。
世界银行集团目前由国际复兴开发银行(即世界银行)、国际开发协会、国际金融公司、多边投资担保机构和解决投资争端国际中心五个成员机构组成。
总部设在美国首都华盛顿。
国际银行家推动的美国联邦货币储备委员会也在此地。
世界银行仅指国际复兴开发银行(IBRD)和国际开发协会(IDA)。
"世界银行集团"则包括IBRD、IDA及三个其它机构,即国际金融公司、多边投资担保机构和解决投资争端国际中心。
这五个机构分别侧重于不同的发展领域,但都运用其各自的比较优势,协力实现其共同的最终目标,即减轻贫困。
世界银行的工作经常受到非政府组织和学者的严厉批评,有时世界银行自己内部的审查也对其某些决定质疑。
往往世界银行被指责为美国或西方国家施行有利于它们自己的经济政策的执行者,此外往往过快、不正确地、按错误的顺序引入的或在不适合的环境下进行的市场经济改革对发展中国家的经济反而造成破坏。
世界银行的真正掌控者是世界银行巨头,他们最终的目的是追逐利润,现在的状况可以说是一个妥协的结果。
今天世界银行的主要帮助对象是发展中国家,帮助它们建设教育、农业和工业设施。
它向成员国提供优惠贷款,同时世界银行向受贷国提出一定的要求,比如减少贪污或建立民主等。
世界银行与国际货币基金组织的历史沿革与作用世界银行(World Bank)和国际货币基金组织(International Monetary Fund,简称IMF)是两个世界重要的国际金融组织,其成立旨在协调国际金融和贸易事务,为全球经济稳定和发展起到了重要作用。
下面将介绍世界银行和IMF的历史沿革与作用。
世界银行(World Bank)世界银行的历史可以上溯到1944年的布雷顿森林会议。
二战后,各国都深刻认识到了经济发展对于战争后的国家重建和国际和平的重要性。
因此,当时各国财政部长和央行行长在布雷顿森林会议上一致决定成立一家新的国际机构,目的是促进经济重建与发展,并解决全球性金融问题。
这家机构最初被称为“国际复兴银行”(International Bank for Reconstruction and Development,简称IBRD),也就是现在所说的世界银行。
世界银行的主要作用是为发展中国家提供资金贷款,以促进这些国家的经济发展。
此外,世界银行还提供技术援助和政策建议,帮助国家解决经济和社会问题。
世界银行的资金主要来自于其成员国,帮助发展中国家实现可持续发展和减贫目标。
世界银行一直致力于支持基础设施建设、教育、医疗卫生、灾后重建等领域的项目,为世界各国的经济发展做出了贡献。
IMF(International Monetary Fund)国际货币基金组织是另一家由多个国家组成的国际机构,目的是维护金融稳定和促进国际贸易。
IMF于1944年成立,其成员国的数量几乎覆盖了全球各个地区。
IMF主要作用是监管全球性金融稳定,防止金融危机的发生。
其方式是通过向成员国提供财政支持和技术援助,帮助这些国家建立健全的货币、财政和金融制度。
此外,IMF还对全球经济形势进行分析和预测,为世界各国提供重要的经济政策建议。
IMF作为全球最重要的经济机构之一,其在国际经济治理和稳定中发挥了重要的作用。
IMF负责监督国际货币、财政和贸易政策,在协调国际经济政策、促进国际合作和解决经济问题等方面,具有重要的领导和协调作用。
世界银行介绍世界银行(World Bank)是世界银行集团的简称,由国际复兴开发银行、国际开发协会、国际金融公司、多边投资担保机构和国际投资争端解决中心五个成员机构组成。
接下来小编为大家整理了世界银行的介绍,希望对你有帮助哦!Until now, many developing countries and undeveloped countries, remains their special thanks to a bank for her urgent loans and high efficient job, which helping them out of the poverty famine and becoming to wealth. This is The World Bank . Her full name is International bank for reconstruction and development. It is a specialized united nations agency established at The Bretton Woods conference, in 1944. A related institution the international monetary fund(IMF) , was created at the same time. The chief objective of the book is to asset, on the reconstruction and development of territories of members by facilitating the investment of capital for productive purpose.Frankly saying the bank grants loans only to member nations for the purpose of financing specific projects. The sources of funds of the bank mainly come from subscription to capital shares. The bank’s working funds are derived from sales of its interest—bearing bonds and from profit on its own operations. It has earned profits every year since 1947.As same as many international financial agencies, The World Bank has her own affiliates. The former is The international finance corps (IFC) established in 1956 .The latter is international Development Association ( I DA) established in 1960.If one country want to get loans from The world bank .The express way that membership in the international monetary funds is a prerequisite for membership in the World Bank and itsaffiliates.In a word , the world will play a more important role ,especially in our Time.。
2023世界银行划分条件世界银行(World Bank)是世界银行集团的简称,它是一个国际组织,由多个国家共同参与,旨在为全球发展提供资金支持。
世界银行将多个发展中国家和发达国家联合起来,共同解决全球发展问题。
世界银行按照借款人的经济条件划分了几个等级,并规定了不同的贷款利率。
以下是世界银行划分条件的概述:1. 低收入国家(LICs)低收入国家是经济最不发达的国家,这些国家的人均收入水平很低,经济结构单一,基础设施落后。
为了帮助这些国家摆脱贫困,世界银行提供了低利率的贷款,并且为这些国家提供了一系列的金融服务和支持。
2. 中等收入国家(MICs)中等收入国家的经济较为发达,人均收入水平较高,经济结构较为多样化,基础设施较为完善。
这些国家通常已经具备了一定的自我发展能力,但是仍然需要外部支持来推动经济发展。
世界银行为这些国家提供了中等的贷款利率,并且提供了一系列的金融服务和支持。
3. 高收入国家(HICs)高收入国家的经济非常发达,人均收入水平很高,经济结构多样化,基础设施完善。
这些国家通常已经具备了较强的自我发展能力,但是仍然需要外部支持来推动经济发展。
世界银行为这些国家提供了较高的贷款利率,并且提供了一系列的金融服务和支持。
4. 最惠国待遇(Most Favored Nations,MFN)最惠国待遇是世界贸易组织的一项原则,它要求各个成员国在贸易、关税、知识产权等方面给予其他成员国最优惠待遇。
世界银行也采用了这一原则,要求借款国在贷款方面给予其他借款国最优惠待遇。
这意味着,如果一个国家能够获得低利率贷款,那么其他国家也应该能够获得相同的贷款条件。
总之,世界银行的划分条件是基于借款人的经济条件和借款国的信用评级等因素来确定的。
这些条件旨在确保借款人能够获得公平的贷款条件,并且确保贷款资金得到妥善使用和偿还。
世界银行数据引用
世界银行(World(Bank)是国际上重要的金融机构之一,提供包括数据在内的多种资源,这些数据被广泛用于研究、政策制定和决策支持。
引用世界银行的数据时,需要遵循以下步骤来确保准确性和可靠性:
1.(访问世界银行官方网站或其公开数据库,如World(Bank(Open(Data。
2.(确定所需数据的准确来源,包括报告名称、出版日期、数据表、图表或数据集的具体位置。
3.(记录数据的详细信息,例如指标定义、测量单位、时间范围和地域覆盖范围。
4.(在引用数据时,注明详细的参考信息,通常包括作者、出版年、文档标题、页码 如适用)、URL或DOI 数字对象标识符)。
5.(使用APA、MLA或其他学术引用标准格式来格式化引用,以符合特定领域的要求。
6.(在分析和解释数据时,保持客观和科学的态度,同时考虑到数据收集和报告的局限性。
7.(如果可能,联系原数据提供者以获取最新或额外的信息,确保数据的准确性和完整性。
8.(在撰写报告或文章时,确保对世界银行的数据进行适当的归属和引用,以尊重知识产权并维护学术诚信。
正确引用世界银行的数据不仅有助于维护研究的透明度和可信度,同时也是对原始数据提供者工作的认可和尊重。
世界银行接口文档一、世界银行简介世界银行(World Bank)成立于1944年,是一家国际金融机构,致力于全球贫困地区的经济发展和减少贫困。
其主要任务是通过向发展中国家提供贷款、赠款和技术援助等方式,支持这些国家实施经济发展计划,提高人民生活水平。
二、世界银行接口文档概述世界银行接口文档是一份详细描述其数据和服务如何对接的指南。
它为开发者提供了一套完整的规范,以便于开发人员了解如何使用世界银行的数据和服务。
接口文档主要包括以下几个部分:1.数据字典:描述了数据集中的字段、数据类型、定义和说明等信息。
2.数据模型:展示了数据之间的关系、实体和属性,以便于理解数据的结构和组织。
3.数据交换格式:介绍了数据传输的格式、编码和协议,如JSON、XML 等。
4.数据服务接口:描述了可供开发人员调用的API接口、参数、响应格式和示例等。
三、接口文档主要内容1.数据字典数据字典是对数据集中各个字段的详细描述,包括字段名、数据类型、长度、小数点后位数、必填项等。
通过数据字典,开发人员可以清晰地了解数据结构的细节,为后续的开发工作奠定基础。
2.数据模型数据模型揭示了数据之间的关系和实体属性,有助于理清数据的内在逻辑。
以世界银行贷款项目为例,数据模型展示了贷款项目实体(LoanProject)与贷款(Loan)之间的关系,以及贷款项目实体与其他实体(如借款国、部门、类别等)之间的关系。
3.数据交换格式数据交换格式说明了数据传输时所采用的编码、格式和协议。
常见的数据交换格式有JSON、XML等。
开发人员可以根据实际需求选择合适的数据交换格式,实现数据的有效传输。
4.数据服务接口数据服务接口描述了可供开发人员调用的API接口、参数、响应格式和示例等。
这有助于开发人员快速掌握如何使用世界银行提供的数据和服务。
例如,如何获取特定国家的贷款项目信息、如何根据贷款编号查询贷款详情等。
四、如何使用世界银行接口文档1.仔细阅读接口文档,了解文档结构和内容。
世界银行宜商环境评价指标世界银行(World Bank)是一个全球性的国际金融机构,致力于减贫和促进经济发展。
宜商环境评价指标是世界银行用于评估各国营商环境的一套指标体系。
宜商环境评价指标主要包括以下几个方面:1.创办企业所需手续和时间:评估开办企业所需的法律程序和行政手续,包括公司注册、取得营业执照等等。
这个指标反映了一个国家或地区开办企业的便利程度和效率。
2.办理建设许可所需时间:评估办理建设许可所需的时间和申请流程。
这个指标反映了一个国家或地区建设项目的审批效率和透明度。
3.办理贷款所需文件:评估办理贷款所需的材料和文件。
这个指标反映了一个国家或地区金融机构对贷款审批的要求和流程。
4.保护投资小股东的权益:评估在一个国家或地区中,投资小股东权益受到的保护程度,包括信息披露、治理规范等方面。
5.纳税义务:评估一个国家或地区税收制度的透明度和效率,包括纳税申报、缴税等方面。
6.跨境贸易便利程度:评估一个国家或地区跨境贸易的便利程度,包括进出口手续、跨境贸易成本等方面。
7.债务清偿:评估一个国家或地区债务清偿的能力和制度,包括法律程序、清偿时间等方面。
以上指标所涵盖的内容非常广泛,从开办企业到债务清偿,覆盖了营商环境的各个方面。
这些指标主要用于评估一个国家或地区的经商环境的优劣,有助于吸引外资和促进经济发展。
世界银行宜商环境评价指标在国际上有广泛的影响力,也是各国政府和国际组织借鉴的重要参考,通过评估营商环境的优劣,帮助国家和地区改善营商环境,吸引更多的投资和促进经济发展。
在过去的几十年中,许多国家和地区通过改善宜商环境取得了显著的经济成就,这也证明了宜商环境评价指标的重要性和有效性。
总之,世界银行的宜商环境评价指标是一个全面评估国家或地区营商环境的指标体系,它对于吸引外资、推动经济发展具有重要意义。
各国和地区应该重视这些指标的改善,通过提高营商环境的质量和效率,为经济发展创造良好的条件。
Trade Liberalization and Labor Market Adjustment in Brazil*Nina PavcnikDartmouth College and NBERAndreas BlomWorld BankPinelopi GoldbergYale University and NBERNorbert SchadyWorld BankOctober 2002AbstractWe study the impact of the 1988-1994 trade liberalization in Brazil on the wage distribution. We explore three main channels through which trade liberalization could have affected the wage distribution: increasing returns to skilled workers due to Hecksher-Ohlin adjustments to trade policy, trade induced skill-biased technological change, and changes in industry wage premiums. Our results suggest the trade reform in Brazil did partially contribute to the growing skill premium through skill-biased technological change, which was partially instigated by the increased foreign competition. We also find that sector specific returns to skill increased by more in sectors with bigger tariff reductions. However, we find little support for Hecksher-Ohlin type adjustments to trade reform. Overall, the effects of trade reforms on wage inequality seem relatively small.* We would like to thank Eric Edmonds, Carolina Sanchez-Paramo and seminar participants at Princeton for helpful suggestions. Correspondence to: Nina Pavcnik, Dartmouth College, Dept. of Economics, Rockefeller Hall 6106, Hanover, NH 03755 or nina.pavcnik@. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the WorldBank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.1.IntroductionPolicy makers often promote trade liberalization and openness as a way to increase living standards and welfare in developing countries. For example, before the 1999 WTO ministerial meeting in Seattle the U.N. secretary general Kofi Annan and the WTO director general Michael Moore urged developed countries to "extend the benefits of free trade fully to the developing world" since free trade enhances economic development and standards of living (Wall Street Journal (1999)).1 Brazil, like many other Latin American economies, followed these policy recommendations and underwent drastic trade liberalization episode from 1988 to 1994 in pursuit of higher living standards and productivity growth. The reforms not only reduced the average tariff level from about 60 percent in 1987 to 15 percent in 1998, but also changed the structure of protection across the industries. These drastic tariff reductions were mirrored in increased import penetration in most manufacturing sectors.While empirical studies have documented that the Brazilian trade reforms have increased efficiency and growth (see Hay (2001), Muendler (2002)), trade liberalization might have also contributed to the growing wage inequality. Several studies have documented growing returns to educated workers in Brazil that coincide with the timing of trade liberalization (see Blom, Holm-Nielsen, and Verner (2001), Green, Arbache, and Dickerson (2001), Behrman, Birdsall, Szekely (2000)).2 Although the causal link between growing skill premium and trade liberalization has not been established, this second development would be alarming for Brazil because it might translate into growing wage inequality in a country with extremely high levels of inequality prior1 Although the theoretical relationship between free trade and welfare is ambiguous, careful empirical work based on cross-country data by Frankel and Romer (1999), confirms that countries that countries with higher exposure to trade have higher living standards as measured by GNP per capita.2 Growing skill premium has been documented in Mexico and many other liberalizing Latin American economies (see Robbins (1996), Cragg and Epelbaum (1996), Hanson and Harrison (1999), Robertson (2000), Behrman, Birdsall, and Szekely (2000), Attanasio, Goldberg, and Pavcnik (2002)).to trade liberalization. Growing skill premium is also puzzling because many have expected that the trade reforms would have lowered income inequality by raising the relative returns to relatively abundant factor of production in Brazilian economy, i.e. the poor, less educated, and unskilled workers.In this paper, we investigate whether trade liberalization has affected wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers in Brazil using data from 1987 to 1998. In particular, we combine detailed micro level worker level information from Pesquisa Mensal de Emprego (PME) with industry level data on tariffs, import penetration, and export exposure to analyze several channels through which trade liberalization might have affected the growing skill premium.3We first analyze whether the growing skill premium could be explained by the mechanism proposed by the Hecksher-Ohlin model of international trade. We test three implications of the model. First, is the growing skill premium consistent with the pattern of tariff reductions observed in Brazil from 1987 to 1988? If tariffs declined proportionately more in sectors that use unskilled labor relatively more intensively, tariff induced changes in product prices could have contributed to the growing in skill premium by increasing the demand for the relatively skilled workers. Second, the Hecksher-Ohlin model would predict labor reallocation from industries that experienced bigger tariff reductions (and hence price reduction and output contraction) towards industries with lower exposure to trade. We explore this mechanism by relating changes in industry share of total employment to tariff changes and other measures of trade exposure. Third, the Hecksher-Ohlin mechanism would predict a decline in the share of skilled workers in industry employment as firms substitute away from skilled labor when skill premium increases after trade liberalization. Our results suggest that Hecksher-Ohlin could in3 Our methodology follows closely the one used in Attanasio, Goldberg, and Pavcnik (2002) for Colombia.principle explain the growing skill premium because tariff reductions were predominantly concentrated in industries with relatively high share of unskilled workers. However, the evidence on the labor market adjustment provides little support for this claim. The structure of industry employment shares remains relatively stable over our sample period and the observed changes in industry employment shares are not in general related to tariffs.4 Most importantly, the share of skilled workers employed in most Brazilian industries has increased concurrently with the growing skill premium, which is not consistent with the Hecksher-Ohlin framework, but is consistent with a positive shock to relative labor demand for skilled workers (for example, skill biased technological change).Although we find scant evidence in support of Hecksher-Ohlin adjustments to trade reform, increased exposure to trade could have affected skill premiums by increasing the demand for skilled labor via skill biased technological change. In particular, Wood (1995) and Acemoglu (2001) argue that firms might adapt skill-biased technology in response to intensified competition from abroad. We explore this hypothesis by checking whether the demand for skilled labor increased more in sectors that experienced larger tariff reductions and larger increases in import penetration. We find that skill-biased technological change was larger in sectors that experienced larger increases in import penetration, suggesting that skill-biased technological change was partly an endogenous response to increased foreign competition.Finally, we explore how trade reforms impacted industry wage premiums. Wage premiums represent the portion of worker wages that cannot be explained through worker or firm characteristics, but are attributed to worker industry affiliation. Most previous literature has concentrated on the effects of trade policy changes on the returns to particular worker4 Although the inclusion of import penetration variable is not theoretically motivated by the Hecksher-Ohlin framework, we find that sectors that experienced increases in import penetration contracted and that tariff declines led to contraction of employment in sectors with higher import penetration.characteristics and the implications of trade policy in the long run, where labor can move across sectors.5 However, worker industry affiliation is crucial in predicting the impact of trade reforms in short- and medium-run models of trade. These models seem particularly relevant in Latin America, where labor market rigidities obstruct labor mobility across sectors (Heckman and Pages (2000)). If workers cannot switch industry employment easily, short- and medium- run models of trade predict that workers in industries with larger tariff reductions are expected to observe a decline in their wages relative to workers with the same observable characteristics in industries with smaller tariff declines.The effect of trade policy on industry wage premiums has two important implications for wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers. First, since different industries employ different proportions of educated and skilled workers, changes in industry wage premiums translate to changes in the relative incomes of skilled and unskilled workers. If tariff reductions are proportionately larger in sectors employing less-skilled workers, and if these sectors observe a decline in their relative wages as a result of trade liberalization, these less-skilled workers will experience a decline in their relative incomes. This effect is distinct from the potential effect of trade liberalization on the economy-wide skill premium. Second, industry wage premiums might vary across workers with different level of skills or education. For example, the more educated workers might be more or less mobile in the labor market and might differ in the accumulated sector specific human capital. If wage premiums differ across workers with different levels of education, and trade liberalization increases the industry specific skill premiums, this could provide an additional channel through which the reforms affect the wage inequality. Our results5Gaston and Trefler (1994), Feliciano (2001), Robertson (2000), Pavcnik and Goldberg (2001), and Arbache and Menezes-Filho (2000) are exceptions. Arbache and Menezes-Filho (2000) find significant evidence of rent-sharing during trade liberalization in Brazilian manufacturing from 1989 to 1995 after they instrument for the value-added with the effective tariffs.suggest that trade reforms did not impact industry wage premiums. However, we find evidence that sector specific skill premiums have increased proportionately more in industries that experienced larger tariff reductions. This evidence is consistent with the sector-specific skill-biased technological change that is concentrated in sectors with larger tariff reductions and trade-induced productivity improvements found by Hay (2001) and Muendler (2002).Overall, we conclude that the trade reform in Brazil did partially contribute to the growing skill premium by impacting skill-biased technological change and industry specific skill premiums. However, we find little support for Hecksher-Ohlin type adjustments to trade reform.The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 of the paper provides background on Brazil's trade regime, describes the labor force data, and overviews the trends in the returns to education. Section 3 explores whether labor market developments in Brazil are consistent with predictionsof the Hecksher-Ohlin trade model and (trade-induced) skill biased technological change. Section 4 analyses the relationship between industry wage premiums and trade reforms. Section 5 concludes.2. Background2.1Trade Policy in BrazilLike many other Latin American countries, Brazil pursued an import substitution policyto shield domestic firms from foreign competition until the 1980s. The high level of tariffs and large number of non-tariff barriers (NTBs) severely hindered the access of foreign good to the Brazilian market and provided high levels of protection to Brazilian firms. The level of protection varied widely across industries. For example, imports from the most protected sector, clothing faced tariffs exceeding 100 percent, followed by sectors such as textiles and rubber that were subject to tariffs exceeding 80 percent in 1987. This suggests that Brazil protectedrelatively unskilled, labor-intensive sectors, which conforms to a finding by Hanson and Harrison (1999) for Mexico and Goldberg and Pavcnik for Colombia (2001). In fact, the Spearman correlation between tariffs and the share of unskilled workers in an industry (measured by the share of workers with less than complete secondary education) is .4 (p-value of .08) in 1987.From 1988 to 1994, however, Brazil underwent a significant trade liberalization that gradually reduced its tariffs and NTBs. The liberalization proceeded in several stages. In 1988 and 1989, the reforms reduced the average tariff levels from about 60 in 1987 to 39 percent in 1989. Kume (2000) and Hay (2001) argue that the initial 1988-1989 tariff reduction had no significant bearing on the exposure of domestic industries to increased foreign competition due to continuous reliance on substantial NTBs. The NTBs such as import licenses, special import programs, and administrative barriers to trade were eliminated in the second stage of the reforms that started in 1990 as the Collor government endeavored to instigate productivity improvements by domestic firms through increased foreign competition.6 The gradual tariff reductions implemented from 1990 to 1994 lowered the average tariff from 34 percent in 1990 to 11 percent tariff in 1995. The government partially reversed these trade reforms in 1995 following the real appreciation of the real that lowered the competitiveness of the manufacturing sector and widened the current account deficit. Nevertheless, the average tariff climbed only slightly between 1995 and 1998.6 Unfortunately, the information on NTBs is not available. This might not be very problematic. First, unlike in many developed countries, tariffs were an important policy instruments in countries such as Brazil. Second, NTBs are inherently hard if not impossible to measure. The common wisdom in the field is that the agencies collecting NTB data take great care in making the data comparable across sectors in a given year, but are less concerned with consistency of the numbers across years. This makes the use of time series data on NTBs troublesome. Finally, we control for import penetration, which partially accounts for the effect of NTBs on various labor market outcomes.This trade liberalization episode provides an excellent setting to study the relationship between wages and trade for several reasons. Table 1 reports the average tariff across 20 manufacturing industries from 1987 to 1998, the period of our study.7 The average tariff declined from 60 percent in 1987 to 15.4 percent in 1998. Second, the reforms changed the structure of protection across industries, as different industries experienced different rates of tariff changes. Figure 1 plots tariffs in 1986 and 1998 in various industries. It shows that declines in tariffs differed across industries, and that the dispersion of tariffs was significantly reduced. The changing structure of protection is also reflected in relatively low year-to-year correlations of industry tariffs from 1987 to 1998. For example, the correlation coefficient between tariffs in 1987, a year preceding the trade reforms, and tariffs in 1989 is .81. The correlation between tariffs in 1987 and 1995, the year after the large reforms were completed, drops to .6. The intertemporal correlation of Brazilian tariffs is similar to the correlation of Colombian tariffs during the 1984-1998, but is significantly lower than the intertemporal correlation in the U.S. tariffs, where the correlation between post-Kennedy GATT Round Tariffs (1972) and post Tokyo GATT round tariffs (1988) is .98. This vast variation in Brazilian tariffs across industries in a given time period and across time provides an excellent setting to study the relationship between trade and wages.The above shifts in Brazil’s trading environment are mirrored in the increase in the import penetration (defined as imports/(output+net imports)) and export exposure (defined as7 Tariff data was obtained from Muendler (2002) at /~muendler/ and are based on Kume, et. al. (2000). The original data provide the tariff levels for 53 sectors at the nivel 80 industrial classification. We have aggregated the data to nivel 50 and made some additional adjustments so that the tariff information corresponds to the level of industry aggregation in the labor force data. The reported tariffs are simple averages of more disaggregated data. When constructing our tariff series, we have also experimented with using nivel 80 import penetration as weights, which yielded similar aggregate means. The correlation between the two series was .98. We thus use the tariffs constructed as simple averages throughout the paper.exports/output) reported in table 2.8 The average import penetration increased from 5.7 % in 1987 to 11.6 % in 1998. The export to output ratio increased from 9.7% to 11.2% in 1998. While the import penetration has almost doubled during this period, it is worthwhile to note that the import penetration in Brazil continues to be relatively low when compared to a country such as Colombia that liberalized during the same period. Colombian manufacturing import penetration was about 21% in 1984 and significantly exceeded 30% after the 1990 tariff reductions (Pavcnik and Goldberg (2001)). This difference could potentially be attributed to a large size of Brazil relative to a country such a Colombia. Moreover, the import penetration increases in Brazil varied significantly across sectors. Figure 2 shows the evolution of industry import penetration and tariffs from 1987 to 1998. Industries with the largest surges in import penetration are clothing (industry 23), transport (industry 12), textiles (industry 22), machinery (industry 8) electronics (industry 10), and pharmaceuticals (industry 20). These are also industries that experienced large tariff declines.2.2 Labor Force DataWe combine the trade exposure measures with labor market data Pesquisa Mensal de Emprego (PME) from Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE), the Brazilian Statistical Bureau from 1987 to 1998. The data set covers the 6 largest metropolitan areas in Brazil: São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro, Porto Alegre, Belo Horizonte, Recife, and Salvador. These metropolitan areas account for about 31.9 million people of the economic active age out of a total of 79 million. Moreover, in 1997, the states of the 6 surveyed metropolitan areas produced 8 Data on import penetration and export to output ratio was obtained from Muendler (2002) at/~muendler/. We made adjustments similar to those for tariffs explained in previous footnote so that the trade exposure information corresponds to the level of industry aggregation in the labor force data. We use industry level trade exposure measures that are weighted by the import penetration of the less disaggregated nivel 80 industry data. However, the correlation between the weighted import penetration series and the import penetration series based on simple averages is .99. Similarly, the correlation between the weighted export to output series and the export to output series based on simple averages is .99.72 percent of the Brazilian GNP.9 Our findings are thus representative of the large and modern parts of the Brazilian labor market, but do not necessarily carry over to the rural economy. Because we focus on manufacturing industries, this might not be very problematic.The data used in this paper consists of people affiliated with any of the 20 manufacturing industries. We include workers or self employed working full-time (defined as working more than 25 hours per week) between ages 15 and 65. We use the data to create several variables that capture worker demographic characteristics such as wage, age, education, geographical location, informal sector of employment, self-employment, and industry affiliation. Our wage measure is hourly wage based on monthly wage divided by 4 times the reported number of hours worked per week. We deflate the hourly wage with the monthly national price index, IPCA. All wages are thus expressed in 1997 September reals. The main indicator for education is completed years of schooling, which is computed using an algorithm based on three survey questions on education. 10 Based on completed years of schooling, we classify workers into those with no complete education, complete elementary education, complete lower secondary education, complete secondary education, and complete tertiary education.11 We also distinguish whether a worker has formal or informal employment on the basis of “carteira assinada”, a signed workcard. A signed workcard entitles a worker to several rights and benefits regulated by the labor market legislations, which enables us to classify whether or not a person works for a formal establishment that complies with labor market regulation. The variable informal is an indicator that is one if the worker is employed in the informal sector of the economy.9 Source: IBGE accounts of gross regional products in current market prices. Brazilian GNP was R$ 864,112 mil and the six states (São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro, Rio Grande do Sul, Minais Gerais, Pernambuco, and Bahia) together accounted for R$ 618,728 mil.10 The algorithm follows the standard conversion used elsewhere (see Lam and Schonie (1993) and Barros and Ramos (1996)).11Elementary education in Brazil consists of four years of schooling. Secondary education, ensino medio, is comprised of two parts, 4-8 years of schooling and 9-11 years of schooling. Tertiary education runs from 12 to15/17 years of schooling.2.3 The Returns to Education in BrazilPrior to exploring whether trade liberalization has contributed to the growing skill premium during our sample period, we summarize the trends in the returns to education during the 1980s and 1990s. Using the same data as this paper (but focusing on workers in all sectors of the economy rather than just manufacturing), Blom, Holm-Nielsen, and Verner (2001) investigate the returns to education for Brazil from 1981 to 1998. Their main findings are summarized in Figure 3, which reports the growth in the returns to education relative to1982 for workers with complete elementary education, complete lower secondary education, complete secondary education, and tertiary education. These estimates are based on the coefficients from earnings regression that controls for age, age squared, gender, whether a person is self employed, and whether the person works in the formal sector. Several interesting finding emerge. First, workers with complete elementary and lower secondary education have experienced a 26% and 35% decline in their return to education relative to 1982, respectively. Second, the returns to complete secondary education have not changed substantially relative to 1982. However, since the returns to elementary and lower secondary education have actually declined during the same period, this translates into a growing return to secondary education relative to the less educated workers. Third, the returns to tertiary education have increased by 24 percent relative to 1982. Given that the returns to elementary and lower secondary education have actually declined, this translates into an even bigger increase in premium associated with complete university degree relative to the return earned by relatively uneducated workers. The above findings are also confirmed for a sample of urban and rural workers by Green, Arbache, and Dickerson (2001) using data from a nationally representative labor survey (PNAD).Given that Brazil underwent drastic trade liberalization from 1987 to 1998, trade liberalization, could in principle account for part of the observed increase in the premium to skilled workers. We explore various channels through which trade could have contributed to the growing returns to skill in the subsequent sections.3. The Economy-Wide Skill Premium and Trade ReformsIn this section we explore whether the rise in the economy-wide skill premium in Brazil is due to Hecksher-Ohlin adjustments to trade reform or skill biased technological change. We first check whether the Brazilian experience supports three implications of the Hecksher-Ohlin model. We then exploit whether the evidence is consistent with skill biased technological change that was potentially induced by trade reforms.The Heckscher-Ohlin model and Stolper-Samuelson theorem relate trade liberalization to changes in the economy-wide skill premium in the long run, when labor and other factors of production are mobile across sectors. Let us consider the predictions of the model in a simplified world that has two sectors, two factors of production (skilled and unskilled labor), and consists of a developed and a developing country. The developing country is assumed to be relatively unskilled labor abundant. When the developing country reduces trade barriers on the imported product, the Stolper-Samuelson theorem predicts that the decline in the price in the import-competing sector will hurt the factor of production used relatively intensively in the production of the imported good (skilled labor) and benefit the factor of production used intensively in the export sector (unskilled labor). According to this Hecksher-Ohlin framework, trade liberalization will then reduce the skill premium in the developing country. This prediction of the model seems to contradict the evidence from developing countries such as Brazil that have experienced an increase in skill premium following trade liberalizations.Despite this seemingly conflicting evidence, we check whether the labor market adjustments in Brazil are in line with predictions of the Hecksher-Ohlin theory. We first investigate if the growing skill premium is consistent with the predictions of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. The increase in the skill premium surrounding Brazilian trade liberalization is exactly what the Stolper-Samuelson theorem would predict if the largest tariff reductions (and thus the largest reductions in the price of goods) occurred in sectors that employed a higher share of unskilled workers.12 Figure 4 relates industry declines in tariffs between 1987 and 1998 to the share of unskilled workers in industry employment (a tariff decline is a positive number in the graph). The figure suggests that industries with higher shares of unskilled workers experienced larger declines in tariffs. This positive correlation between tariff declines and unskilled labor intensity of the industry is also confirmed in a regression of annual declines in tariffs on the share of unskilled workers in 1987. The coefficient on the share of unskilled workers is 3.97 (T-statistic=1.88). These results suggest that tariff cuts in Brazil, like in Mexico and Colombia (see Hanson and Harrison (1998) and Attanasio, Goldberg, and Pavcnik (2002)) were concentrated in unskilled labor intensive industries. As a result, the Hecksher-Ohlin adjustment to trade reform could in principle account for the growing skill premium in Brazil. However, this is not necessarily the case.We thus test whether labor market adjustment in Brazil is consistent with other implications of Hecksher-Ohlin adjustments to trade reform. In particular, the model predicts that sectors that experience tariff induced declines in relative prices should experience a contraction in employment, while industries with increased tariff induced relative prices should expand. As a result, labor should migrate from the sectors with the largest tariff reductions to the12 Throughout the paper, we classify workers with complete secondary or tertiary degree as skilled. All other workers are classified as unskilled.。