美国司法部1984年《企业兼并指南》英文版
- 格式:pdf
- 大小:111.01 KB
- 文档页数:33
美国企业兼并的立法规制及对我国的启示_经济法(1) -企业兼并是市场经济发展的必然产物,在西方经历了漫长的百年历程,至今,西方再次掀起第五次企业兼并狂潮。
由于企业兼并涉及到社会各个领域,且对经济发展、平等竞争、社会公平等起着重大的作用。
因此,各国都纷纷制定一系列法律,对企业兼并制定规制措施,有效地规范和促进了企业兼并行为的进行,从而最终促进了社会经济的向前发展。
对西方企业兼并立法规制进行研究分析,对目前我国正在进行的国有经济战略重组和调整将起到积极的促进作用,对建立和完善我国企业兼并的法律制度,将起着重要的借鉴作用。
一、美国企业兼并的立法规制(一)美国企业兼并的立法概况美国是企业兼并发生较早的国家之一,其兼并立法包括国家立法和州立法两部分。
其内容以反托拉斯法、各类证券法、兼并准则和公司法等组成。
其立法用意是反对垄断、保护合法兼并和维护公平竞争。
1890年,联邦政府通过的《谢尔曼反托拉斯法》(sherman Antitrust Act of 1890)构成美国反托拉斯法的基础,它是“保护贸易和商业受非法限制和垄断之害的法案”。
1914年,国会通过了《联邦贸易委员会法》(Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914)和《克莱顿法》(The clayton Antitrust Act of 1914),前者的主要目的是防止“商业中的不公平竞争和不公正的或欺骗性行为”。
后者则是为了防止垄断力量的形成和积累。
1936年,国会通过了《罗宾逊—帕特曼法》(The Ropinson-patman Act of 1936),主要是为了反对价格歧视。
1950年,国会通过了《塞勒-凯弗维尔法》(Celler-KefaurerAmendmant),主要为了堵住《克莱顿法》关于在购买会大大削弱或导致垄断时仍允许大公司购买竞争者的资产的这一漏洞。
为了便于执行反托拉斯法,从1968年开始,美国司法部每隔若干年还颁布一次兼并准则,美国先后颁布了1968、1982、1984等三部兼并准则。
盖世特约:美国企业收购之法律指南目录1. 引言与概览 (1)2. 保护私有信息—保密协议 (1)3. 初步分析 (1)4. 为完成对美国企业的收购在美国成立公司 (2)5. 制定交易条款—意向书、谅解备忘录或条款清单 (3)6. 交易方法—资产收购、股份收购和合并 (5)7. 法律尽职调查 (6)8. 最终收购协议 (7)9. 政府审批或通知 (8)10. 交易的交割 (11)11. 结论 (11)乔杰思合伙人律师美国科尔律师事务所JAMES R. CAMBRIDGE美国密歇根州底特律市伍德沃德大街500 号 2500 室500 Woodward Avenue, Suite 2500Detroit, Michigan 48226-3427邮编: 48226-3427电话:+1 313 961 0200传真:+1 313 961 0388电邮:jcambridge@Phone:( 313) 961- 0200Fax:(313) 961- 0388Email:jcambridge@乔杰思先生是美国科尔律师事务所的资深合伙人,主要从事商业法和国际贸易。
他的客户包括技术、制造、金融、服务、零售和房地产等行业的中国和美国企业。
乔杰思先生在帮助中国公司来美国建立或扩展业务上有着非常丰富的经验。
乔杰思先生是美国科尔律师事务所中美国际商业法部门的主管,并被列入《美国法律名人录》和《美国最佳律师》名录。
他还被列入《底特律最佳律师》,《密歇根州超级律师》和《钱伯斯美国领先商业律师名录》。
乔杰思先生是密歇根州市政管理局的成员,市政管理局是由密歇根州州长里克·斯奈德和密歇根州立法机关共同建立的一个权威机构,致力于监督密歇根州各个城市和学区之间的共享服务的发展。
乔杰思先生也是密歇根州律师基金会的研究员,在密歇根州,只有少数具有最高标准的专业精神和社会服务的律师能够被授予此荣誉。
丁超逸律师美国科尔律师事务所CHAOYI DING美国密歇根州底特律市伍德沃德大街500 号 2500 室500 Woodward Avenue, Suite 2500Detroit, Michigan 48226-3427Phone:( 313) 963- 2607Fax:(313) 961- 0388Email:cding@邮编: 48226-3427电话:+1 313 961 0200传真:+1 313 961 0388电邮:cding@丁律师是美国科尔律师事务所中美国际商业法部门的成员,主要从事商业法,公司法和国际贸易。
并购的历史与理论发展企业兼并又称吸收合并,指两家或者更多的独立企业,公司合并组成一家企业,通常由一家占优势的公司吸收一家或者多家公司。
收购是指一家企业用现金或者有价证券购买另一家企业的股票或者资产,以获得对该企业的全部资产或者某项资产的所有权,或对该企业的控制权。
这就是通常人们讲的企业并购,是兼并、收购两种形式的合称。
与企业并购意义相关的另一个概念是企业合并,是指两个或两个以上的企业合并成为一个新的企业,合并完成后,多个法人变成一个法人。
关于企业并购的历史问题,虽然企业并购开始的时间不长,但是人们仍然像对待其他历史事件一样,并不是很清晰。
在张雪奎教授的研究中,世界历史上的第一次企业并购,是伴随世界第一个现代股份制公司荷兰的东印度公司同时出现的。
1602年3月20日以航海贸易起家的荷兰,为了增强航海贸易的能力,发行650万荷兰盾的股票,先后整合了14家大型、300家小型的海上贸易公司,使荷兰拥有了海上马车夫的称号。
以集资形式建立的东印度公司到了1669年时,已经成为世界上最富有、最强大的企业,拥有超过150艘商船、40艘战舰、五万名员工和一万名雇佣兵,年股息高达40%的巨无霸。
由此可见企业并购的威力,现在的股份制企业和并购模式,仍然是沿用的荷兰东印度公司模式。
由于当时的企业并购情况不是很清楚,因此西方的史学家们在研究并购历史的时候,采用的是近百年来的并购历史。
一、企业并购的历史特点以横向并购为特征的第一次并购浪潮19世纪下半叶,科学技术取得巨大进步,大大促进了社会生产力的发展,为以铁路,冶金,石化,机械等为代表的行业大规模并购创造了条件,各个行业中的许多企业通过资本集中组成了规模巨大的垄断公司。
在1899年美国并购高峰时期,公司并购达到1208起,是1896年的46倍,并购的资产额达到22.6亿美元。
1895年到1904年的并购高潮中,美国有75%的公司因并购而消失。
在工业革命发源地——英国,并购活动也大幅增长,在1880-1981年间,有665家中小型企业通过兼并组成了74家大型企业,垄断着主要的工业部门。
美国企业兼并收购历史与现状分析在美国,无论一个企业是独资、合伙或公司形式,只要该企业能紧跟时代步伐适时转变它的所有制形式,则该企业就会有相当大的成长壮大的机会。
而这种所有制形式的转变往往是通过收购新的企业、卖掉旧的企业、或与现有的其它企业合并成新的企业等方式来实现的。
据统计,美国20世纪80年代初上市的企业已有40%兼并了其它企业或被其他企业收购。
在20世纪的80年代里,一些所谓的“企业狙击手”们通过收购价值被低估的公司,再全部或分拆卖掉,获得了超额的短期收益。
但近年来的企业兼并收购一般都基于长期的发展战略目标。
兼并收购发展的四个阶段企业兼并和收购的区别在于兼并和收购过程中财务处理的设计,是非常技术性。
兼并是指两个或更多的的公司根据双方或多方的利益组成一个新的公司。
收购是指一个公司通过部分或全部购买另一家公司而成为一个控股公司,收购公司要承接被收购公司全部或相关部分的债权和债务。
而一个公司只出售部分资产给另外一个公司,则叫部分出售(divesti ture)。
可以说,美国企业的兼并收购活动贯穿于美国经济发展的全部过程,而且表现形式多样。
企业兼并浪潮和兼并方式往往与经济发展变化相关。
美国历史上兼并活动有多次高峰期,其中之一发生在1881-1911年,当时经营石油和钢铁等基础工业的资本家们通过他们巨大的垄断信用购买许多(达到控股程度)竞争对手的股票来控制市场。
这种同行业里竞争对手之间的兼并称为平行兼并(horizontalmergers)。
平行兼并的目的是获得规模经济效益和排除竞争。
美国政府反垄断托拉斯运动不断高涨和美孚石油公司(StandardOil)在1911年解散标志着美国历史上这次平行兼并潮的结束。
美国历史上另一次兼并高潮发生在上个世纪20年代,当时美国经济蒸蒸日上,出现了许多某行业里处于某一阶段(比如原材料、生产、流通等)的公司吸收或加入同行业里不同阶段的公司,这种兼并称为垂直兼并(verticalmergers)。
[摘要] 本文首先对并购实质、并购作用、并购发生的十种理论进行综述,接着对国内外并购研究现状进行评价,涉及并购绩效、并购方式、并购成功标准、并购可能性、目标企业价值,提出天时、地利、人和的并购成功标准和合作博弈在并购中的重要性。
[关键词]并购;目标企业;动机;效应一、并购理论1。
企业性质与并购。
企业是国民经济的细胞,其发展方式有内涵式发展和外延式发展。
并购(M&A,是兼并与收购的合称)是资本运作的高级形式,是企业的外部发展战略,是企业的一种外部投资,是资本在某一产业中实施或进或退的重要途径,也是对产业进行结构调整、资源整合的重要手段.关于企业性质有各种假设:①新古典主义企业理论认为企业是一个“原子"式的“经济人”,企业掌握充分信息,使边际收益等于边际成本,实现利润最大化,利用市场机制无代价,但与现实不符;②西蒙(1955)的“有限理性"及满意原则,企业追求满意的利润;③鲍莫尔(1959)的“最大销售收入"模型认为,现代企业股东的所有权和企业经理掌握的经营权相分离,经理往往出于自身利益而追求企业规模;④马里斯(1963)的“最大增长率”模型,企业追求比其过去和比其他企业发展得更快;⑤威廉姆森(1963)的“经理效用最大化”理论,认为职业经理人追求自身利益的最大效应;⑥科斯等的节约交易费用理论,认为市场和企业是配置资源的两种方式,采用哪种方式取决于谁的交易成本更低;⑦近年来形成的与单边的股东至上主义不同的股东、经理、员工、政府、银行等利益相关者共同治理理论等。
企业的经营目的不同,可能产生不同的并购动机,其对应的动机理论也不同。
企业并购的实质是夺取目标企业的控制权,为取得投资收益的参股不是并购.股权转让后受让方不是企业的第一大股东,但若具有重大事项决策权,也是并购。
但一般情况下,股份(股权)最多的股东掌握企业的控制权,绝大多数并购是为夺取第一大股东的地位。
控股有绝对控股(50%)和相对控股(50%),而并购以获得相对控股者居多,因为相对于绝对控股,它可减少并购方的并购资金支出而又能达到并购目的,缺点是对企业的控制力弱。
第十二章美国的并购政策法规1,主要内容体系构成联邦证券法中的威廉姆斯法案(1968)反垄断法体系兼并准则各州有关并购的法案特征及发展趋势案例分析2,威廉姆斯法案(1968)13(d)部分规范大宗股票收购14(d)部分规范要约收购14(e)部分规范要约收购中的不恰当行为14(f)部分规范信息披露13(e)部分规范发行者的回购行为3.从三个方面保护被并方股东利益要求更多信息披露要求要约收购给予被并方股东考虑期给予被并方股东起诉并购方的权利4,美国反垄断法的目标第一是经济目标,它通过保护竞争来最大限度地提高经济效率。
第二是政治目标,反托拉斯法禁止经济权力的过度集中,从而有利于保障政府的稳定。
第三个目标是社会和道德方面的。
美国人认为,竞争过程有利于培养人们独立向上的性格和相互竞争的精神,而这些是美国民族道德的精髓,所以,竞争机制需要加以保护(S.J.Davis and K. M. Murphy,2000)。
5,美国反垄断法体系美国反垄断法的执行机构美国联邦贸易委员会(FTC)与司法部两者同时负责实施反托拉斯法。
一般来讲,司法部办理的案子大多与价格固定(pricefixing,即卡特尔)或垄断有关,FTC的管辖范围则包括企业兼并和不公平竞争等方面。
除了司法部和FTC之外,消费者或企业也可以起诉厂家违犯反托拉斯法。
为了减少违法行为的发生,美国采用所谓“三倍惩罚”(treble damages)的办法。
如果一企业因违犯了反托拉斯法而对其竞争对手或消费者造成危害,按法律规定,它将付给受害者三倍于实际损失的罚款,情节严重者,则可能会进监牢。
联邦贸易委员会的五名委员,由总统提名,经国会批准。
但他们的任期是七年,而总统的任期是四年。
这样,联邦贸易委员会的人事组成,就不像司法部长那样易受总统政策的影响,从而提高了联邦贸易委员会执法的相对独立性。
6,美国并购准则1968年兼并准则1968年的兼并准则规定了确定的标准,用以说明什么样的兼并得不到批准。
美国反垄断法主要是:禁止垄断协议和独占行为;限制市场集中度、企业兼并等行为;消费者权益保护和禁止不正当竞争行为等以下是引用:“美国的反垄断法由三部法律组成,分别是1890年颁布的《谢尔曼反托拉斯法》、1914年颁布的《联邦贸易委员会法》和《克莱顿法》。
《谢尔曼反托拉斯法》是世界反垄断法的开山鼻祖,主要内容是禁止垄断协议和独占行为,此后制定的另两部法律则是对这一法律的补充和完善。
《克莱顿法》的主要内容是限制集中、合并等行为。
《联邦贸易委员会法》则增加了消费者权益保护和禁止不正当竞争行为等内容。
该法还建立了联邦贸易委员会。
美国出台反垄断法有其特定时代背景,主要是源于19世纪末的反托拉斯运动,其根本目的在于保护消费者利益、促进市场竞争。
根据美国反垄断法,一旦企业被裁定有垄断嫌疑,将可能面临罚款、监禁、赔偿、民事制裁、强制解散、拆分等多种惩罚。
而且,由于美国实行惩罚性罚款,一旦企业被认定违犯反垄断法,罚款金额将三倍于损害金额。
在具体司法操作上,美国奉行诉讼“多轨制”。
其中,司法部可直接对涉嫌垄断的企业提起民事诉讼和刑事诉讼,美国许多经典案例都是在司法部诉讼下得以完成的。
美国联邦贸易委员会也可以直接进行裁决或提起民事诉讼。
此外,受损企业或普通消费者也可直接对涉嫌垄断的企业提起民事诉讼,并要求三倍的损失赔偿。
在100多年的司法实践中,美国在反垄断裁决上产生了一系列对美国乃至世界经济有深远影响的著名案例。
比如,曾一统天下的美国洛克菲勒标准石油公司1911年被肢解为34个独立石油公司;曾垄断美国电话市场的美国电报电话公司于1984年被分拆成专营长途电话业务的电报电话公司和7个地区性电话公司。
最新的一个著名案例则是微软垄断案。
美国司法部于上世纪90年代对微软公司提出起诉,称其通过视窗操作系统捆绑销售其他软件的行为构成了市场垄断,微软因此一度面临被一分为二的危险。
经过漫长的法律诉讼,微软虽然逃脱了被解体的命运,但同时不得不向竞争对手支付7.5亿美元的巨额赔●以前,美国对垄断的界定,主要根据企业规模和产品的市场份额来判断· 全国格斗大赛开始· 银行卡安全快捷换Q币· 沟通无极限手机Q时代· 魔法表情秀出百变心情· 全国格斗大赛开始· QQ秀秀出个性真自我●现在,美国的反垄断矛头已转向滥用垄断地位与实力●今后,美国的反垄断实践,可能将聚焦保障公平竞争、推动技术创新1890年的《谢尔曼法》是美国也是世界上第一部反托拉斯法。
15 U.S.C. § 18 (1982). Mergers subject to section 7 are prohibited if their effect "may be1substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly." 15 U.S.C. § 1 (1982). Mergers subject to section 1 are prohibited if they constitute a "contract,2combination..., or conspiracy in restraint of trade." They update the Guidelines issued by the Department in 1982. The Department may from time 3to time revise the Merger Guidelines as necessary to reflect any significant changes in enforcement policy or to clarify aspects of existing policy.1984 MERGER GUIDELINES1.PURPOSE AND UNDERLYING POLICY ASSUMPTIONS 1.0These Guidelines state in outline form the present enforcement policy of the U.S. Department of Justice ("Department") concerning acquisitions and mergers ("mergers") subject to section 7 of the Clayton Act or section 1 of the Sherman Act.They describe the general principles and specific 1 2 standards normally used by the Department in analyzing mergers. By stating its policy as simply and 3clearly as possible, the Department hopes to reduce the uncertainty associated with enforcement of the antitrust laws in this area.Although the Guidelines should improve the predictability of the Department's merger enforcement policy, it is not possible to remove the exercise of judgment from the evaluation of mergers under the antitrust laws. Because the specific standards set forth in the Guidelines must be applied to a broad range of possible factual circumstances, strict application of those standards may provide misleading answers to the economic questions raised under the antitrust laws. Moreover, the picture of competitive conditions that develops from historical evidence may provide an incomplete answer to the forward-looking inquiry of the Guidelines. Therefore, the Department will apply the standards of the Guidelines reasonably and flexibly to the particular facts and circumstances of each proposed merger.The Guidelines are designed primarily to indicate when the Department is likely to challenge mergers, not how it will conduct the litigation of cases that it decides to bring. Although relevant inParties seeking more specific advance guidance concerning the Department's enforcement4intentions with respect to any particular merger should consider using the Business Review Procedure. 28C.F.R. § 50.6.2the latter context, the factors contemplated in the standards do not exhaust the range of evidence that the Department may introduce in court.4The unifying theme of the Guidelines is that mergers should not be permitted to create or enhance "market power" or to facilitate its exercise. A sole seller (a "monopolist") of a product with no good substitutes can maintain a selling price that is above the level that would prevail if the market were competitive. Where only a few firms account for most of the sales of a product, those firms can in some circumstances either explicitly or implicitly coordinate their actions in order to approximate the performance of a monopolist. This ability of one or more firms profitably to maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period of time is termed "market power." Sellers with market power also may eliminate rivalry on variables other than price. In either case, the result is a transfer of wealth from buyers to sellers and a misallocation of resources."Market power" also encompasses the ability of a single buyer or group of buyers to depress the price paid for a product to a level that is below the competitive price. The exercise of market power by buyers has wealth transfer and resource misallocation effects analogous to those associated with the exercise of market power by sellers.Although they sometimes harm competition, mergers generally play an important role in a free enterprise economy. They can penalize ineffective management and facilitate the efficient flow of investment capital and the redeployment of existing productive assets. While challenging competitive-ly harmful mergers, the Department seeks to avoid unnecessary interference with that larger universe of mergers that are either competitively beneficial or neutral. In attempting to mediate between these dual concerns, however, the Guidelines reflect the congressional intent that merger enforcement should interdict competitive problems in their incipiency.2.MARKET DEFINITION AND MEASUREMENT2.0Using the standards stated below, the Department will define and measure the market for each product or service (hereinafter "product") of each of the merging firms. The standards in the Guidelines are designed to ensure that the Department analyzes the likely competitive impact of a merger within economically meaningful markets—i.e., markets that could be subject to the exercise of market power. Accordingly, for each product of each merging firm, the Department seeks to define a market in which firms could effectively exercise market power if they were able to coordinate their actions. Formally, a market is defined as a product or group of products and a geographic area in which it is sold such that a hypothetical, profit-maximizing firm, not subject to price regulation, that was the only present and future seller of those products in that area would impose a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price above prevailing or likely future levels. The group of products and geographic area that comprise a market will be referred to respectively as the "product market" and the "geographic market."In determining whether one or more firms would be in a position to exercise market power, it is necessary to evaluate both the probable demand responses of consumers and the probable supply responses of other firms. A price increase could be made unprofitably by any of four types of demand or supply responses: 1) consumers switching to other products; 2) consumers switching to the same product produced by firms in other areas; 3) producers of other products switching existing facilities to the production of the product; or 4) producers entering into the production of the product by substantially modifying existing facilities or by constructing new facilities. Each type of response is considered under the Guidelines.In determining whether any of these responses are probable, the Department usually must rely on historical market information as the best, and sometimes the only, indicator of how the market will function in the future. It is important to note, however, that the Guidelines are fundamentally concerned with probable future demand or supply responses.Sections 2.1 through 2.4 describe how product and geographic markets will be defined under these Guidelines and how market shares will be calculated.3Although discussed separately, product market definition and geographic market definition are 5interrelated. In particular, the extent to which buyers of a particular product would shift to other products in the event of a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price must be evaluated in the context of the relevant geographic market.42.1Product Market Definition 2.11General ApproachThe Department will first determine the relevant product market with respect to each of the products of each of the merging firms. In general, the Department will include in the product market a group of products such that a hypothetical firm that was the only present and future seller of those products (a "monopolist") could profitably impose a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price. That is, assuming that buyers could respond to an increase in price for a tentatively identified product group only by shifting to other products, what would happen? If readily available alternatives were, in the aggregate, sufficiently attractive to enough buyers, an attempt to raise price would not prove profitable, and the tentatively identified product group would prove to be too narrow.Specifically, the Department will begin with each product (narrowly defined) produced or sold by each merging firm and ask what would happen if a hypothetical monopolist of that product imposed a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price.If the price increase would 5 cause so many buyers to shift to other products that a hypothetical monopolist would not find it profitable to impose such an increase in price, then the Department will add to the product group the product that is the next-best substitute for the merging firm's product and ask the same question again. This process will continue until a group of products is identified for which a hypothetical monopolist could profitably impose a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price. The Department generally will consider the relevant product market to be the smallest group of products that satisfies this test.In the above analysis, the Department will use prevailing prices of the products of the merging firms and possible substitutes for such products. However, the Department may use likely future prices when changes in the prevailing prices can be predicted with reasonable reliability. Changes inFor example, in a merger between retailers, the relevant price would be the retail price of a 6product to consumers. In the case of a merger among oil pipelines, the relevant price would be the tariff—the price of the transportation service.For example, a larger increase may be appropriate if the "price" to be increased is a tariff or 7commission that constitutes a small fraction of the price of the product being transported or sold.5price may be predicted on the basis of, for example, expected changes in regulations that directly affect price.In general, the price for which an increase will be postulated will be whatever is considered to be the price of the product at the stage of the industry being examined.In attempting to determine 6 objectively the effect of a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price, the Department in most contexts will use a price increase of five percent lasting one year. However, what constitutes a "small but significant and non-transitory" increase in price will depend on the nature of the industry,and the Department at times may use a price increase that is larger or smaller than five percent.For 7 the purposes of its analysis, the Department will assume that the buyers and sellers immediately become aware of the price increase.2.12Relevant EvidenceAlthough direct evidence of the likely effect of a future price increase may sometimes be available, it usually will be necessary for the Department to infer the likely effects of a price increase from various types of reliable, circumstantial evidence. The postulated "small but significant and nontransitory" price increase provides an objective standard by which to analyze the available evidence. Thus, in evaluating product substitutability, the Department will consider all relevant evidence but will give particular weight to the following factors:1) Evidence of buyers' perceptions that the products are or are not substitutes, particularly if those buyers have actually considered shifting purchases between the products in response to changes in relative price or other competitive variables;2) Differences in the price movements of the products or similarities in price movements over a period of years that are not explainable by common or parallel changes in factors such as costs of inputs, income, or other variables;Price discrimination requires that sellers be able to identify those buyers and that other buyers be 8unable profitably to purchase and resell to them.63) Similarities or differences between the products in customary usage, design, physical composition, and other technical characteristics; and4) Evidence of sellers' perceptions that the products are or are not substitutes, particularly if business decisions have been based on those perceptions.2.13 Price DiscriminationThe analysis of product market definition to this point has assumed that price discrimination—charging different buyers different prices for products having the same cost, for example—would not be possible after the merger. Existing buyers sometimes will differ significantly in their assessment of the adequacy of a particular substitute and the ease with which they could substitute it for the product of the merging firm. Even though a general increase in price might cause such significant substitution that it would not be profitable, sellers who can price discriminate could raise price only to groups of buyers who cannot easily substitute away.If such price discrimination 8 is possible, the Department will consider defining additional, narrower relevant product markets consisting of particular uses of the product for which a hypothetical monopolist could profitably im-pose a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price.2.2Identification of Firms that Produce the Relevant ProductIn most cases, the Department's evaluation of a merger will focus primarily on firms that currently produce and sell the relevant product. In addition, the Department may include other firms in the market if their inclusion would more accurately reflect probable supply responses. The following are examples of circumstances in which such additional firms would be included in the market.Under other analytical approaches, production substitution sometimes has been reflected in the 9description of the product market. For example, the product market for stamped metal products such as automobile hub caps might be described as "light metal stamping," a production process rather than a product. The Department believes that the approach described in the text provides a more clearly focused method of incorporating this factor in merger analysis. If production substitution among a group of products is nearly universal among the firms selling one or more of-those products, however, the Department may use an aggregate description of those markets as a matter of convenience.The amount of sales or capacity to be included in the market is a separate question10discussed in Section 2.4, below.72.21Production SubstitutionThe same productive and distributive facilities can sometimes be used to produce and sell two or more products that buyers do not regard as good substitutes. Production substitution refers to the shift by a firm in the use of facilities from producing and selling one product to producing and selling another. Depending upon the cost and speed of that shift, production substitution may allow firms that do not currently produce the relevant product to respond effectively to an increase in the price of that product.9If a firm has existing productive and distributive facilities that could easily and economically be used to produce and sell the relevant product within one year in response to a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price, the Department will include that firm in the market. In this 10context, a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price will be determined in the same way in which it is determined in product market definition. In many cases, a firm that could readily convert its facilities from the production of one product to another would have significant difficulty distributing or marketing the new product or for some other reason would find the substitution unprofitable. Such firms will not be included in the market. The competitive significance of such firms, as well as those that will not be included in the market because they must construct significant new productive and distributive facilities, will be considered in evaluating entry conditions generally.See Section 3.3 (Ease of Entry).2.22Durable ProductsSome long-lived products may continue to exert competitive influence after the time of original sale. If, under the standards stated in Section 2.1, recycled or reconditioned products represent good substitutes for new products, the Department will include in the market firms that recycle or recondition those products.2.23Internal ConsumptionCaptive production and consumption of the relevant product by vertically integrated firms are part of the overall market supply and demand. Such firms may respond to an increase in the price of the relevant product in either of two ways. They may begin selling the relevant product, or alternatively, they may continue to consume all of their production but increase their production of both the relevant product and products in which the relevant product is embodied. Either kind of supply response could frustrate collusion by firms currently selling the relevant product. If a firm would be likely to respond either way to a "small but significant and non-transitory” increase in price, the Department will include that firm in the market. In this context, a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price will be determined in the same way in which it is determined in product market definition.2.3Geographic Market Definition2.31General ApproachFor each product market of each merging firm, the Department will determine the geographic market or markets in which that firm sells. The purpose of geographic market definition is to establish a geographic boundary that roughly separates firms that are important factors in the competitive analysis of a merger from those that are not. Depending on the nature of the product and the competitive circumstances, the geographic market may be as small as part of a city or as large as the entire world. Also, a single firm may operate in a number of economically discrete geographic markets.8In general, the Department seeks to identify a geographic area such that a hypothetical firm that was the only present or future producer or seller of the relevant product in that area could profitably impose a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price. That is, assuming that buyers could respond to a price increase within a tentatively identified area only by shifting to firms located outside the area, what would happen? If firms located elsewhere readily could provide the relevant product to the hypothetical firm's buyers in sufficient quantity at a comparable price, an attempt to raise price would not prove profitable, and the tentatively identified geographic area would prove to be too narrow.In defining the geographic market or markets affected by a merger, the Department will begin with the location of each merging firm (or each plant of a multiplant firm) and ask what would happen if a hypothetical monopolist of the relevant product at that point imposed a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price. If this increase in price would cause so many buyers to shift to products produced in other areas that a hypothetical monopolist producing or selling the relevant product at the merging firm's location would not find it profitable to impose such an increase in price, then the Department will add the location from which production is the next-best substitute for production at the merging firm's location and ask the same question again. This process will be repeated until the Department identifies an area in which a hypothetical monopolist could profitably impose a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price. The "smallest market" principle will be applied as it is in product market definition. Both the price in which an increase will be postulated and what constitutes a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price will be determined in the same way in which it is determined in product market definition.2.32Relevant EvidenceAlthough direct evidence of the likely effect of a future price increase may sometimes be available, it usually will be necessary for the Department to infer the likely effects of a price increase from various types of reliable, circumstantial evidence. The postulated "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price provides an objective standard by which to analyze the available evidence. Thus, in evaluating geographic substitutability, the Department will consider all relevant evidence but will give particular weight to the following factors:9Geographic price discrimination against a group of buyers is more likely when. other buyers 11cannot easily purchase and resell the relevant product to them. Such arbitrage is particularly difficult where the product is sold on a delivered basis and where transportation costs are a significant percentage of the final cost.101) The shipment patterns of the merging firm and of those firms with which it actually competes for sales;2) Evidence of buyers having actually considered shifting their purchases among sellers at different geographic locations, especially if the shifts corresponded to changes in relative price or other competitive variables;3) Differences in the price movements of the relevant product or similarities in price movements over a period of years that are not explainable by common or parallel changes in factors such as the cost of inputs, income, or other variables in different geographic areas;4) Transportation costs;5) Costs of local distribution; and6) Excess capacity of firms outside the location of the merging firms.2.33Price DiscriminationThe analysis of geographic market definition to this point has assumed that geographic price discrimination—charging different prices net of transportation costs for the same product to buyers in different locations, for example—would not be possible after the merger. As in the case of product market definition, however, where price discrimination is possible,the Department will consider 11 defining additional, narrower geographic markets consisting of particular locations in which a hypo-thetical monopolist could profitably impose a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price.2.34Foreign CompetitionIn general, the foregoing standards will govern market definition, whether domestic or international. Although voluntary or involuntary quotas may prevent foreign competitors from increasing their imports into the United States in response to a domestic price increase, the Department will not exclude foreign competitors from the relevant market solely on the basis of theIf exchange rates fluctuate significantly, making comparable dollar calculations for different 12firms difficult, then the volume of unit sales may be a better measure of market share than dollar sales and may be used instead.11quotas. This is primarily because it frequently is difficult to determine and measure the effectiveness and longevity of a particular quota or any offsetting supply response from firms in countries not sub-ject to the quota. The Department will consider effects of a quota as a separate factor in interpreting the significance of market shares and market concentration. See Section 3.23 (Special Factors Affecting Foreign Firms).2.4Calculating Market SharesThe Department normally will include in the market the total sales or capacity of all domestic firms (or plants) that are identified as being in the market under Sections 2.2 and 2.3. Market shares can be expressed either in dollar terms through measurement of sales, shipments, or production, or in physical terms through measurement of sales, shipments, production, capacity, or reserves. As a practical matter, the availability of data often will determine the measurement basis. When the availability of data allows a choice, dollar sales or shipments generally will be used if branded or relatively differentiated products are involved, and physical capacity, reserves, or dollar production-generally will be used if relatively homogeneous, undifferentiated products are involved.In some cases, however, total sales or capacity may overstate the competitive significance of a firm. The Department will include only those sales likely to be made or capacity likely to be used in the market in response to a "small but significant and nontransitory" increase in price, for example,with respect to firms included in the market under Sections 2.21 (Production Substitution) and 2.23(Internal Consumption). Similarly, a firm's capacity may be so committed elsewhere that it would not be available to respond to an increase in price in the market. In such cases, the Department also may include a smaller part of the firm's sales or capacity.To the extent available information permits, market shares will be assigned to foreign competitors in the same way in which they are assigned to domestic competitors. If dollar sales or shipments are used to measure shares of domestic firms, the market shares of foreign firms will be measured using dollar sales in, or shipments to, the relevant market.If physical capacity, reserves,12Markets can range from atomistic, where very large numbers of firms that are small relative 13to the overall size of the market compete with one another, to monopolistic, where one firm controls the entire market. Far more common, and more difficult analytically, is the large middle range of instances where a relatively small number of firms account for most of the sales in the market.12or dollar production is used for domestic firms, the shares of foreign firms will be measured in terms of the capacity or reserves likely to be used to supply, or production that is likely to be shipped to,the relevant market in response to a "small but significant and nontransitory" price increase. If shipments from a particular country to the United States are subject to a quota, the market shares assigned to firms in that country will not exceed the amount of shipments by such firms allowed under the quota. Current shipments rather than capacity or reserves may be used for foreign firms if it is impossible reliably to quantify the proportion of the firms' capacity, reserves, or production that would be devoted to the relevant market in response to a "small but significant and nontransitory"increase in price because of, for example, the lack of available data regarding foreign capacity or the commitment of such capacity to other markets. Finally, a single market share may be assigned to a country or group of countries if firms in that country or group of countries act in coordination or if necessitated by data limitations.3.HORIZONTAL MERGERS 3.0Where the merging firms are in the same product and geographic market, the merger is horizontal. In such cases, the Department will focus first on the post-merger concentration of the market and the increase in concentration caused by the merger. For mergers that result in low market concentration or a relatively slight increase in concentration, the Department will be able to determine without a detailed examination of other factors that the merger poses no significant threat to competition. In other cases, however, the Department will proceed to examine a variety of other factors relevant to that question.3.1Concentration and Market SharesMarket concentration is a function of the number of firms in a market and their respective market shares. Other things being equal, concentration affects the likelihood that one firm, or a13。