Cointegration and Forward and Spot Exchange Rate Regressions
- 格式:pdf
- 大小:240.72 KB
- 文档页数:36
外文题目:Can macroeconomic variables explain long term stock market movements?A comparison of the US and Japan出处:School of Economics and Finance, University of St Andrews, St Andrews, UK,作者:Andreas Humpe Peter MacmillanCan macroeconomic variables explain long term stock marketmovements?A comparison of the US and JapanBy Andreas Humpe Peter Macmillan原文:ABSTRACTWithin the framework of a standard discounted value model we examine whether a number of macroeconomic variables influence stock prices in the US and Japan. A cointegration analysis is applied in order to model the long term relationship between industrial production, the consumer price index, money supply, long term interest rates and stock prices in the US and Japan. For the US we find the data are consistent with a single cointegrating vector, where stock prices are positively related to industrial production and negatively related to both the consumer price index and a long term interest rate. We also find an insignificant (although positive) relationship between US stock prices and the money supply. However, for the Japanese data we find two cointegrating vectors. We find for one vector that stock prices are influenced positively by industrial production and negatively by the money supply. For the second cointegrating vector we find industrial production to be negatively influenced by the consumer price index and a long term interest rate. These contrasting results may be due to the slump in the Japanese economy during the 1990s and consequent liquidity trap.Keywords: Stock Market Indices, Cointegration, Interest Rates.I. Introduction.A significant literature now exists which investigates the relationship between stock market returns and a range of macroeconomic and financial variables, across a number of different stock markets and over a range of different time horizons. Existing financial economic theory provides a number of models that provide a framework for the study of this relationship.One way of linking macroeconomic variables and stock market returns is through arbitrage pricing theory (APT) (Ross, 1976), where multiple risk factors can explain asset returns. While early empirical papers on APT focussed on individual security returns, it may also be used in an aggregate stock market framework, where a change in a given macroeconomic variable could be seen as reflecting a change in an underlying systematic risk factor influencing future returns. Most of the empirical studies based on APT theory, linking the state of the macro economy to stock market returns, are characterised by modelling a short run relationship betweenmacroeconomic variables and the stock price in terms of first differences, assuming trend stationarity. For a selection of relevant studies see inter alia Fama (1981, 1990), Fama and French (1989), Schwert (1990), Ferson and Harvey (1991) and Black, Fraser and MacDonald (1997). In general, these papers found a significant relationship between stock market returns and changes in macroeconomic variables, such as industrial production, inflation, interest rates, the yield curve and a risk premium.An alternative, but not inconsistent, approach is the discounted cash flow or present value model (PVM)1. This model relates the stock price to future expected cash flows and the future discount rate of these cash flows. Again, all macroeconomic factors that influence future expected cash flows or the discount rate by which these cash flows are discounted should have an influence on the stock price. The advantage of the PVM model is that it can be used to focus on the long run relationship between the stock market and macroeconomic variables. Campbell and Shiller (1988) estimate the relationship between stock prices, earnings and expected dividends. They find that a long term moving average of earnings predicts dividends and the ratio of this earnings variable to current stock price is powerful in predicting stock returns over several years. They conclude that these facts make stock prices and returns much too volatile to accord with a simple present value model. Engle and Granger (1987) and Granger (1986) suggest that the validity of long term equilibria between variables can be examined using cointegration techniques. These have been applied to the long runrelationship between stock prices and macroeconomic variables in a number of studies, see inter alia Mukherjee and Naka (1995), Cheung and Ng (1998), Nasseh and Strauss (2000), McMillan (2001) and Chaudhuri and Smiles (2004). Nasseh and Strauss (2000), for example, find a significant long-run relationship between stock prices and domestic and international economic activity in France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Switzerland and the U.K. In particular they find large positive coefficients for industrial production and the consumer price index, and smaller but nevertheless positive coefficients on short term interest rates and business surveys of manufacturing. The only negative coefficients are found on long term interest rates. Additionally, they find that European stock markets are highly integrated with that of Germany and also find industrial production, stock prices and short term rates in Germany positively influence returns on other European stock markets (namely France, Italy, Netherlands, Switzerland and the UK).In this paper, we will draw upon theory and existing empirical work as a motivation to select a number of macroeconomic variables that we might expect to be strongly related to the real stock price. We then make use of these variables, in a cointegration model, to compare and contrast the stock markets in the US and Japan. In contrast to most other studies we explicitly use an extended sample size of most of the last half century, which covers the most severe stock market booms in US and Japan. While Japans’ h ay days have been in the late 1980s, the US stock market boom occurred during the 1990s and ended in 2000. Japans’ stock market has not yet fully recovered from a significant decline during the 1990s, and at the time of writing, trades at around a quarter of the value it saw at its peak in 1989.2The aim of this paper is to see whether the same model can explain the US and Japanese stock market while yielding consistent factor loadings. This might be highly relevant, for example, to private investors, pension funds and governments, as many long term investors base their investment in equities on the assumption that corporate cash flows should grow in line with the economy, given either a constant or slowly moving discount rate. Thus, the expected return on equities may be linked to future economic performance. A further concern might be the impact of the Japanese deflation on real equity returns. In this paper, we make use of the cointegration methodology, to investigate whether the Japanese stock market has broadly followed the same equity model that has been found to hold in the US.In the following section, we briefly outline the simple present value model of stock price formation and make use of it in order to motivate our discussion of the macroeconomic variables we include in our empirical analysis. In the third section we briefly outline the cointegration methodology, in the fourth section we discuss our results and in the fifth section we offer a summary and some tentative conclusions based on our results.As suggested by Chen, Roll and Ross (1986), the selection of relevant macroeconomic variables requires judgement and we draw upon both on existing theory and existing empirical evidence. Theory suggests, and many authors find, that corporate cash flows are related to a measure of aggregate output such as GDP or industrial production4. We follow, Chen, Roll and Ross (1986), Maysami and Koh (1998) and Mukherjee and Naka (1995) and make use of industrial production in this regard.Unanticipated inflation may directly influence real stock prices (negatively) through unexpected changes in the price level. Inflation uncertainty may also affect the discount rate thus reducing the present value of future corporate cash flows. DeFina (1991) has also argued that rising inflation initially has a negative effect on corporate income due to immediate rising costs and slowly adjusting output prices, reducing profits and therefore the share price. Contrary to the experience of the US, Japan suffered periods of deflation during the late 1990s and early part of the 21st century, and this may have had some impact on the relationship between inflation and share prices. The money supply, for example M1, is also likely to influence share prices through at least three mechanisms: First, changes in the money supply may be related to unanticipated increases in inflation and future inflation uncertainty and hence negatively related to the share price; Second, changes in the money supply may positively influence the share price through its impact on economic activity; Finally, portfolio theory suggests a positive relationship, since it relates an increase in the money supply to a portfolio shift from non-interest bearing money to financial assets,including equities. For a further discussion on the role of the money supply see Urich and Wachtel (1981), Rogalski and Vinso (1977) and Chaudhuri and Smiles (2004). The interest rate directly changes the discount rate in the valuation model and thus influences current and future values of corporate cash flows. Frequently, authors have included both a long term interest rate (e.g. a 10 year bond yield) and a short term interest rate (e.g. a 3 month T-bill rate)5. We do not use a short term rate as our aimhere is to find a long term relationship between the stock market and interest rate variables. Changes in the short rate are mainly driven by the business cycle and monetary policy. In contrast, the long term interest rate should indicate the longer term view of the economy concerning the discount rate.For our long term rate using the US data we have chosen a 10 year bond yield, however for Japan we instead use the official discount rate. This is due largely to data availability constraints and that the market for 10 year bonds (and similar maturities) in Japan has not been liquid for most of the time period covered. We should note that the discount rate is an official lending rate for banks in Japan, which implies it is generally lower than a market rate. Unlike many studies; see inter alia Mukherjee and Naka (1995) and Maysami and Koh (2000); we do not include the exchange rate as an explanatory variable. We reason the domestic economy should adjust to currency developments and thus reflect the impact of fo reign income due to firms’ exports measured in domestic currency over the medium run. Additionally, in the white paper on the Japanese Economy in 1993, published by the Japanese Economic Planning Agency, it has been pointed out that the boom in the economy during the late 1980s has been driven by domestic demand rather than exports (Government of Japan, 1993).In contrast to our study, many researchers have based their analysis on business cycle variables or stock market valuation measures such as the term spread or 7default spread for the former category or dividend yield or earnings yield for the latter. Examples of those papers include Black, Fraser and MacDonald (1997); Campbell and Hamao (1992); Chen, Roll and Ross (1986); Cochran, DeFina and Mills (1993); Fama (1990); Fama and French (1989); Harvey, Solnik and Zhou (2002) and Schwert (1990). These variables are usually found to be stationary and as we plan to model long term equilibrium using non stationary variables we do not included them in our model.As McAdam (2003) has confirmed, the US economy has been characterized by more frequent but less significant downturns relative to those suffered by the Japanese economy. This might be explained by a higher capital and export orientated Japanese economy relative to the US. We might therefore expect higher relative volatility in corporate cash flows and hence also in Japanese share prices. A priori, therefore, share prices in Japan may be more sensitive to changes in industrial production, although the greater relative volatility may also influence the estimated coefficient standard errors in any regression equation. However, previous research (seeBinswanger, 2000) has found that although both stock markets move positively with economic output, that the coefficient for output on equity returns tends to be larger for the US data relative the Japanese data. Campbell and Hamao (1992) also find smaller positive coefficients for the dividend price ratio and the long-short interest rate spread on stock market returns in Japan relative to the US in a sample covering monthly data from 1971 to 1990. Thus the intuitive expectation of higher coefficients in Japan due to higher capital and export exposure has not been confirmed empirically in existing research. Japan’s banking crisis and subsequent asset deflation during the 1990s could have changed significantly the influence of a number of variables, particularly the interest rate and money supply.To our knowledge, there has not been any empirical study of the present value model in Japan after the early 1990s and thus the severe downturn with low economic growth and deflation. Existing studies of the Japanese stock market before 1990 include Brown and Otsuki (1990), Elton and Gruber (1988), and Hamao (1988), although these papers mainly consider stationary business cycle variables and risk factors and therefore cannot give an indication of the empirical relationships we might expect to find in our model.In this paper we compare the US and Japan over the period January 1965 until June 2005. The use of monthly data gives the opportunity to analyse a very rich data set, to our knowledge earlier papers have only analysed shorter periods or have made use of a lower data frequency. This allows us to include the impact of the historically high volatility of both stock markets. The US stock market showed very high returns between 1993 and 1999, while from 2000 until 2003 returns have been very large and negative. In the Japanese stock market during the period from 1980 through to 1990, returns have in the main been large and positive while they tend to have been large negative for most of years between 1990 and 2003. The impact of recent problems to the Japanese banking sector is also captured in our data (see Government of Japan, 1993). Most existing research has been applied to US data and very little is known about the differences between US and Japanese stock market valuation. This paper investigates the differences and common patterns in both countries in order to verify whether the same variables that explain aggregate stock market movement in the US can also be used to do so in Japan.ConclusionIn order to achieve a deeper understanding of long term stock market movements, a comparison of the US and Japanese stock market, using monthly data over the last 40years has been conducted. Using US data we found evidence of a single cointegration vector between stock prices, industrial production, inflation and the long interest rate. The coefficients from the cointegrating vector, normalised on the stock price, suggested US stock prices were influenced, as expected, positively by industrial production and negatively by inflation and the long interest rate. However, we found the money supply had an insignificant influence over the stock price. In Japan, we found two cointegrating vectors. One normalised on the stock price provided evidence that stock prices are positively related to industrial production but negatively related to the money supply. We also found that for our second vector, normalised on industrial production, that industrial production was negatively related to the interest rate and the rate of inflation. An explanation of the difference in behaviour between the two stock markets may lie in Japan’s slump after 1990 an d its consequent liquidity trap of the late 1990s and early 21st century.外文题目:Can macroeconomic variables explain long term stock market movements?A comparison of the US and Japan出处:School of Economics and Finance, University of St Andrews, St Andrews, UK,作者:Andreas Humpe Peter Macmillan*译文:宏观经济变量可以解释长期的股市走势?一个美国和日本比较研究在一个标准的贴现值模型的框架内,我们考察宏观经济变量是否影响美国和日本的股票价格。
河北省邯郸市武安市武安市第一中学2024-2025学年高二上学期10月期中英语试题一、听力选择题1.What does the woman hurry to do?A.Go to the classroom.B.Catch the bus.C.Go up one floor.2.What does the woman think of the medicine?A.It doesn’t work.B.It makes her tired.C.It makes her have no appetite. 3.How many cookies were left?A.Three.B.Four.C.Ten.4.What may the speakers do next?A.Have a conference.B.Exchange seats.C.Take the fight.5.Where might the speakers be?A.In a library.B.At the man’s home.C.In a supermarket.听下面一段较长对话,回答以下小题。
6.What does the woman like about the old design?A.The red walls.B.The piano.C.The floor.7.What will the speakers do next?A.Play the piano.B.Have something to eat.C.Enjoy the live music.听下面一段较长对话,回答以下小题。
8.What are the speakers doing?A.Having a party B.Travelling to France.C.Watching a movie. 9.Who is the woman speaking to?A.Her brother.B.Her friend.C.Her father.听下面一段较长对话,回答以下小题。
*Thanks to Charles Engel for his insights on the issues presented herein and to VinayDatar for motivating me to write the paper. Updates to the paper can be found at/~ezivot/homepage.htm.Cointegration and Forward and Spot Exchange Rate RegressionsbyEric Zivot *Department of EconomicsUniversity of WashingtonBox 353330Seattle, WA 98195-3330ezivot@June 12, 1997Last Revision: September 29, 1998AbstractIn this paper we investigate in detail the relationship between models of cointegration between the current spot exchange rate, s t , and the current forward rate, f t , and models of cointegration between the future spot rate, s t+1, and f t and the implications of this relationship for tests of the forward rate unbiasedness hypothesis (FRUH). We argue that simple models of cointegration between s t and f t more easily capture the stylized facts of typical exchange rate data than simple models of cointegration between s t+1 and f t and so serve as a natural starting point for the analysis of exchange rate behavior. We show that simple models of cointegration between s t and f t imply rather complicated models of cointegration between s t+1 and f t . As a result, standard methods are often not appropriate for modeling the cointegrated behavior of (s t+1, f t )N and we show that the use of such methods can lead to erroneous inferences regarding the FRUH.21. IntroductionThere is an enormous literature on testing if the forward exchange rate is an unbiased predictor of future spot exchange rates. Engel (1996) provides the most recent review. The earliest studies, e.g. Cornell (1977), Levich (1979) and Frenkel (1980), were based on the regression of the log of the future spot rate, s t+1, on the log of the current forward rate, f t . The results of these studies generally support the forward rate unbiasedness hypothesis (FRUH). Due to the unit root behavior of exchange rates and the concern about the spurious regression phenomenon illustrated by Granger and Newbold (1974), later studies, e.g. Bilson (1981), Fama (1984) and Froot and Frankel (1989),concentrated on the regression of the change in the log spot rate, )s t+1, on the forward premium, f t -s t . Overwhelmingly, the results of these studies reject the FRUH. The most recent studies, e.g.,Hakkio and Rush (1989), Barnhart and Szakmary (1991), Naka and Whitney (1995), Hai, Mark and Yu (1997), Norrbin and Reffett (1996), Newbold, et. al. (1996), Clarida and Taylor (1997), Barnhart,McNown and Wallace (1998) and Luintel and Paudyal (1998) have focused on the relationship between cointegration and tests of the FRUH. The results of these studies are mixed and depend on how cointegration is modeled.Since the results of Hakkio and Rush (1989), it is well recognized that the FRUH requires that s t+1 and f t be cointegrated and that the cointegrating vector be (1,-1) and much of the recent literature has utilized models of cointegration between s t+1 and f t . It is also true that the FRUH requires s t and f t to be cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1) and only a few authors have based their analysis on models of cointegration between s t and f t . In this paper we investigate in detail the relationship between models of cointegration between s t and f t and models of cointegration between s t+1 and f t and the implications of this relationship for tests of the FRUH. We argue that simple models of cointegration between s t and f t more easily capture the stylized facts of typical exchange rate data than simple models of cointegration between s t+1 and f t and so serve as a natural starting point for the analysis of exchange rate behavior. Simple models of cointegration between s t and f t imply rather complicated models of cointegration between s t+1 and f t . In particular, starting with a first order bivariate vector error correction model for (s t , f t )N we show that the implied cointegrated model for (s t+1, f t )N is nonstandard and does not have a finite VAR representation. As a result,standard VAR methods are not appropriate for modeling (s t+1, f t )N and we show that the use of such3methods can lead to erroneous inferences regarding the FRUH. In particular, we show that tests of the null of no-cointegration based on common cointegrated models for (s t+1, f t )N are likely to be severely size distorted. In addition, using the implied triangular cointegrated representation for (s t+1,f t )N we can explicitly characterize the OLS bias in the levels regression of s t+1 on f t . Based on this representation, we can show that the OLS estimate of the coefficient on f t in the levels regression is downward biased (away from one) even if the FRUH is true. Finally, we show that the results of Naka and Whitney (1995) and Norrbin and Reffett (1996) supporting the FRUH are driven by the specification of the cointegration model for (s t+1, f t )N .The plan of the paper is as follows. In section 2, we discuss the relationship between cointegration and the tests of the forward rate unbiasedness hypothesis. In section 3 we present some stylized facts of exchange rate data typically used in investigations of the FRUH. In section 4, we discuss some simple models of cointegration between s t and f t that capture the basic stylized facts about the data and we show the restrictions that the FRUH places on these models. In section 5, we consider models of cointegration between s t+1 and f t that are implied by models of cointegration between s t and f t . In section 6, we use our results to reinterpret some recent findings concerning the FRUH reported by Naka and Whitney (1995) and Norrbin and Reffett (1996). Our concluding remarks are given in section 7.2. Cointegration and the Forward Rate Unbiasedness Hypothesis: An OverviewThe relationship between cointegration and the forward rate unbiasedness hypothesis has been discussed by several authors starting with Hakkio and Rush (1987). Engel (1996) provides a comprehensive review of this literature and serves as a starting point for the analysis in this paper.Following Engel (1996), the forward exchange rate unbiasedness hypothesis (FRUH) under rational expectations and risk neutrality is given byE t [s t+1] = f t ,(1)where E t [@] denotes expectation conditional on information available at time t. Using the terminology of Baillie (1989), FRUH is an example of the “observable expectations” hypothesis. The FRUH is usually expressed as the levels relationship4s t+1 = f t + >t+1,(2)where >t+1 is a random variable (rational expectations forecast error) with E t [>t+1] = 0. It should be kept in mind that rejection of the FRUH can be interpreted as a rejection of the model underlying E t [@]or a rejection of the equality in (1) itself.Two different regression equations have generally been used to test the FRUH. The first is the “levels regression”s t+1 = µ + $f f t + u t+1(3)and the null hypothesis that FRUH is true imposes the restrictions µ = 0, $f = 1 and E t [u t+1] = 0. In early empirical applications authors generally focused on testing the first two conditions and either ignored the latter condition or informally tested it using the Durbin-Watson statistic. Most studies using (3) found estimates of $f very close to 1 and hence supported the FRUH. Some authors, e.g.Barnhart and Szakmary (1991), Liu and Maddala (1992), Naka and Whitney (1995) and Hai, Mark and Wu (1997), refer to testing µ = 0, $f = 1 as testing the forward rate unbiasedness condition (FRUC). Testing the orthogonality condition E t [u t+1] = 0, conditional on not rejecting FRUC, is then referred to as testing forward market efficiency under rational expectaions and risk neutrality.Assuming s t and f t have unit roots, i.e., s t , f t ~ I (1), (see, for example, Messe and Singleton (1982),Baillie and Bollerslev (1989), Mark (1990), Liu and Maddala (1992), Crowder (1994), or Clarida and Taylor (1997) for empirical evidence), then the FRUH requires that s t+1 and f t be cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1, -1) and that the stationary, i.e., I (0), cointegrating residual, u t+1, satisfy E t [u t+1] = 0. Notice that testing FRUC is then equivalent to testing for cointegration between s t+1 and f t and that the cointegrating vector is (1,-1) and testing forward market efficiency is equivalent to testing that the forecast error, s t+1 - f t , has conditional mean zero.The FRUH assumes rational expectations and risk neutrality. Under rational expectations,if agents are risk averse then a stationary time-varying risk premium exists and the relationship between s t+1 and f t becomess t+1 = f t - rp t re + >t+1,(4)where rp t re = f t - E t [s t+1] represents the stationary rational expectations risk premium. As long as rp tre is stationary s t+1 and f t will be cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1, -1) but f t will be a biased predictor of s t+1 provided rp t re is predictable using information available at time t . In this regard, the5FRUC is a misleading acronym since if the FRUC is true forward rates are not necessarily unbiased predictors of future spot rates. Since the FRUC is equivalent to cointegration between s t+1 and f t and that the cointegrating vector is (1,-1), which implies that s t+1 and f t trend together in the long-run but may deviate in the short-run, it is more appropriate to call this the long-run forward rate unbiasedness condition (LRFRUC).Several authors, e.g. Messe and Singleton (1982), Meese (1989) and Isard (1995), have stated that since s t and f t have unit roots the levels regression (3) is not a valid regression equation because of the spurious regression problem described in Granger and Newbold (1974). However,this is not true if s t+1 and f t are cointegrated. What is true is that if s t+1 and f t are cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1, -1), which allows for the possibility of a stationary time varying risk premium so that u t+1 in (3) is I (0), then the OLS estimates from (3) will be super consistent (converge at rate T instead of rate T ½) for the true value $f = 1 but generally not efficient and biased away from 1 in finite samples so that the asymptotic distributions of t -tests and F -tests on µ an $f will follow non-standard distributions, see Corbae, Lim and Ouliaris (1992). Hence, even if the FRUH is not true due the existence of a stationary risk premium so that (3) is a misspecified regression, OLS on (3) still gives a consistent estimate of $f = 1. More importantly, there are simple modifications to OLS that yield asymptotically unbiased and efficient estimates of the parameters of (3) in the presence of general serial correlation and heteroskedasticity and these modifications should be used to make inferences about the parameters in the levels regression 1. In this sense, the levels regression (3) under cointegration is asymptotically immune to the omission of a stationary risk premium. Hai, Mark and Wu (1997) use Stock and Watson’s (1993) dynamic OLS estimator on the levels regression (3) and provide evidence that s t+1 and f t are cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1, -1).The second regression equation used to test the FRUH is the “differences equation”)s t+1 = µ* + "s (f t - s t ) + u*t+1(5)and the null hypothesis that FRUH is true imposes the restrictions µ* = 0, "s = 1 and E t [u*t+1] = 0.Empirical results based on (5), surveyed in Engel (1996), overwhelmingly reject the FRUH. In fact,typical estimates of "s across a wide range of currencies and sampling frequencies are significantly negative. This result is often referred to as the forward discount anomaly, forward discount bias or forward discount puzzle and seems to contradict the results based on the levels regression (3). Given6that s t , f t ~ I (1), for (5) to be a “balanced regression” (i.e., all variables in the regression are integrated of the same order) the forward premium, f t - s t , must be I (0) or, equivalently, f t and s t must be cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1). Assuming that covered interest rate parity holds, the forward premium is simply the interest rate differential between the respective countries and there are good economic reasons to believe that such differentials do not contain a unit root. Hence, tests of the FRUH based on (5) implicitly assume that the forward premium is I (0) and so such tests are conditional on f t and s t being cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1). In this respect, (5) can be thought of as one equation in a particular vector error correction model (VECM) for (f t , s t )N .2Horvath and Watson (1995) and Clarida and Taylor (1997) use VECM-based tests and provide evidence that f t and s t are cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1).As noted by Fama (1984), the negative estimates of "s are consistent with rational expectations and market efficiency and imply certain restrictions on the risk premium. To see this,note that under rational expectations we may write)s t+1=(f t - s t ) - rp t re +>t+1,(6)so that the difference regression (5) is misspecified if risk neutrality fails. Since all variables in (6) are I (0), if the risk premium is correlated with the forward premium then the OLS estimate of "s in the standard differences regression (5), which omits the risk premium, will be biased away from the true value of 1. Hence the negative estimates of "s from (5) can be interpreted as resulting from omitted variables bias. As discussed in Fama (1984), for omitted variables bias to account for negativeestimates of "s it must be true that cov(E t [s t+1] - s t , rp t re ) < 0 and var(rp t re ) > Var(E t [s t+1] - s t ). Hence,as Engel (1996) notes, models of the foreign exchange risk premium should be consistent with these two inequalities.The tests of the FRUH based on (3) and (5) involve cointegration either between s t+1 and f t or f t and s t . As Engel (1996) points out, sinces t+1 - f t = )s t+1 - (f t - s t )it is trivial to see under the assumption that f t and s t are I(1) that (i) if s t and f t are cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1) then s t+1 and f t must be cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1); and (ii) if s t+1 and f t are cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1) then s t and f t must be cointegrated with cointegrating vector (1,-1). Cointegration models for (s t , f t )N and (s t+1, f t )N can both be used to7describe the data and test the FRUH but the form of the models used can have a profound impact on the resulting inferences. For example, we show that a simple first order vector error correction model for (s t , f t )N describes monthly data well and leads naturally to the differences regression (5) from which the FRUH is easily rejected. In contrast, we show that some simple first order vector error correction models for (s t+1, f t )N , which are used in the empirical studies of Naka and Whitney (1995) and Norrbin and Reffett (1996), miss some important dynamics in monthly data and as a result indicate that the FRUH appears to hold. Hence, misspecification of the cointegration model for (s t+1, f t )N can explain some of the puzzling empirical results concerning tests of the FRUH.In the next section, we describe some stylized facts of monthly exchange rate data that are typical in the analysis of the FRUH. In the remaining sections we use these facts to motivate certain models of cointegration for (s t , f t )N and (s t+1, f t )N to support our claims regarding misspecification and tests of the FRUH.3. Some Stylized Facts of Typical Exchange Rate DataLet f t denote the log of the forward exchange rate in month t and s t denote the log of the spot exchange rate. We focus on monthly data for which the maturity date of the forward contract is the same as the sampling interval to avoid modeling complications created by overlapping data. For our empirical examples, we consider forward and spot rate data (all relative to the U.S. dollar) on the pound, yen and Canadian dollar taken from Datastream 3. Figure 1 shows time plots of s t+1, f t - s t (forward premium), and s t+1 - f t (forecast error) for the three currencies and Table 1 gives some summary statistics of the data. Spot and forward rates behave very similarly and exhibit random walk type behavior. The forward premiums are all highly autocorrelated but the forecast errors show very little autocorrelation. The variances of )s t+1 and )f t+1 are roughly ten times larger than the variance of f t - s t and are similar to the variance of s t+1 - f t . For all currencies, )s t+1, )f t+1 and s t+1 - f t are negatively correlated with f t - s t . Any model of cointegration with cointegrating vector (1, -1) for (s t ,f t )N or (s t+1, f t )N should capture these basic stylized facts.4. Models of Cointegration between f t and s t4.1 Vector error correction representation8The stylized facts of the monthly exchange rate data reported in the previous section can be captured by a simple cointegrated VAR(1) model for y t = (f t , s t )N . This simple model has also recently been used by Godbout and van Norden (1996). Before presenting the empirical restults, we begin this section with a review of the properties of such a model. The general bivariate VAR(1) model for y t isy t = µ + M y t-1 + ,t ,where ,t ~ iid (0,E ) and E has elements F ij (i,j = f,s ), and can be reparameterized as)y t = µ + A y t-1+ ,t (7)where A = M - I . Under the assumption of cointegration, A has rank 1 and there exist 2 × 1 vectors " and $ such that A = "$N . Using the normalization $ = (1, -$s )N , (7) becomes the vector error correction model (VECM))f t = µf + "f (f t-1 - $s s t-1) + ,ft ,(8a))s t = µs + "s (f t-1 - $s s t-1) + ,st .(8b)Since spot and forward rates often do not exhibit a systematic tendency to drift up or down it may be more appropriate to restrict the intercepts in (8) to the error correction term. That is, µf = -"f µc and µs = -"s µc . Under this restriction s t and f t are I (1) without drift and the cointegrating residual,f t - $s s t , is allowed to have a nonzero mean µc 4.With the intercepts in (8) restricted to the error correction term, the VECM can be solved to give a simple AR(1) model for the cointegrating residual $N y t - µc = f t - $s s t - µc . Premultiplying (7)by $N and rearranging givesf t - $s s t - µc = N (f t-1 - $s s t-1 - µc ) + 0t ,(9)where N = 1 + $N " = 1 + ("f - $s "s ) and 0t = $N ,t = ,ft - $s ,st . Since (9) is simply an AR(1) model,the cointegrating residual is stable and stationary if *N * = *1 + ("f - $s "s )* < 1. Notice that if "f =$s "s then the cointegrating residual is I (1) and f t and s t are not cointegrated.The exogeneity status of spot and forward rates with regard to the cointegrating parameters " and $ was the focus of attention in Norrbin and Reffett (1996) so it is appropriate to discuss this issue in some detail. Exogeneity issues in error correction models are discussed at length in Johansen (1992, 1995), Banerjee et. al. (1993), Urbain (1993), Ericsson and Irons (1994) and Zivot (1998).For our purposes weak exogeneity of spot or forward rates for the cointegrating parameters " and9$ places restrictions on the parameters of the VECM (8). In particular, if f t is weakly exogenous with respect to ("s , $s )N then "f = 0 and efficient estimation of the cointegrating parameters can be made from the single equation conditional error correction model)s t = µs + "s (f t-1 - $s s t-1) + (s )f t + <st ,(10a)where (s = F s -s 1 F fs and <st is uncorrelated with ,ft . Similarly, if s t is weakly exogenous with respect to ("f , $s )N then "s = 0 and efficient estimation of the cointegrating parameters can be made from the single equation conditional error correction model)f t = µf + "f (f t-1 - $s s t-1) + (f )s t + <ft(10b)where (f = F f -f 1 F fs and <ft is uncorrelated with ,st .If $s = 1 then the forward premium is I (0) and follows an AR(1) process and the VECM (8)becomes)f t = µf + "f (f t-1 - s t-1) + ,ft ,(11a))s t = µs + "s (f t-1 - s t-1) + ,st .(11b)Notice that (11b) is simply the standard differences regression (5) used to test the FRUH. Further,if "f and "s are of the same sign and magnitude then the implied value of N in (9) is close to 1 and this corresponds to the stylized fact that the forward premium is stationary but very highly autocorrelated.Also, the implied variance of the of the forward premium from (9) is F 00 = F ff + F ss - 2D fs (F ff F ss )½ and will be very small relative to the variances of )f t and )s t given the stylized facts that F ff . F ss and D fs . 1.The FRUH places testable restrictions on the VECM (8). Necessary conditions for the FRUH to hold are (i) s t and f t are cointegrated (ii) $s = 1 and (iii) µc = 0. In addition, the FRUH requires that "s = 1 in order for the forecast error in (2) to have conditional mean zero. It is important to stress that, together, these two restrictions limit both the long-run and short-run behavior of spot and forward rates. Applying these restrictions, (8), led one period, becomes)f t+1 = "f (f t - s t ) + ,f,t+1,(12a))s t+1 = (f t - s t ) + ,s,t+1.(12b)Notice that the FRUH requires that the expected change spot rate is equal to the forward premium or, equivalently, that the adjustment to long-run equilibrium occurs in one period. The change in the forward rate, on the other hand, is directly related to the persistence of interest rate differentials now10measured by "f since N = 1 + ("f - 1) = "f . Stability of the VECM under the FRUH requires that *"f *< 1. Thus, the FRUH is consistent with a highly persistent forward premium.The representation in (12) shows that weak exogeneity of spot rates with respect to the cointegrating parameters is inconsistent with the FRUH because if spot rates are weakly exogenous then "s = 0 and the FRUH cannot hold. In addition if the FRUH is true and forward rates are weakly exogenous then (12) cannot capture the dynamics of typical data. To see this, suppose that forward rates are weakly exogenous so that "f = 0. Since F ss . F ff . F sf = F ² it follows that (s . (f . 1. If µs = 0, "s = 1 and $s = 1, then (10a) becomess t = f t-1 + )f t + <t = f t + <twhich simply states that the current spot rate is equal to the current forward rate plus a white noise error. This result is clearly inconsistent with the data since it implies that the forward premium is serially uncorrelated.4.2 Phillips’ triangular representation .Another useful representation of a cointegrated system is Phillips’ (1991) triangular representation, which is similar to the triangular representation of a limited information simultaneous equations model. This representation is most useful for studying the asymptotic properties of cointegrating regressions and Baillie (1989) has advocated its use for testing rational expectations restrictions in cointegrated VAR models. This representation is also used by Naka and Whitney (1995) to test the FRUH. The general form of the triangular representation for y t isf t = µc + $s s t + u ft ,(13a)s t = s t-1 + u st ,(13b)where the vector of errors u t = (u ft , u st )N = (f t - $s s t - µc , )s t )N has the stationary moving average representation u t = R (L)e t where and e t is i.i.d. with mean zero andR (L )'j 4k '0R k L k ,j 4k '0|k |R k <4covariance matrix V . Equation (13a) models the (structural) cointegrating relationship and (13b) isa reduced form relationship describing the stochastic trend in the spot rate. For a given VECM representation, the triangular representation is simply a reparameterization. For the VECM (8) with the restricted constant, the derived triangular representation is given by (13a)-(13b) withu ft = N u f,t-1 + 0t ,(13c)11u st = "s u ft-1 + ,st ,(13d)and N , "s , 0t and ,st are as previously defined. Equation (13c) models the disequilibrium error (which equals the forward premium if $s = 1) as an AR(1) process and (13d) allows the lagged error to affect the change in the spot rate. Let e t = (0t , ,st )N . Then the vector u t = (u ft , u st )N = (f t - $s s t - µc ,)s t )N has the VAR(1) representation u t = Cu t-1 + e t whereC'N "s ,V'F 00F 0F s 0F ,Hence, R (L) = (I - C L)-1. As noted previously, F 00 is very small relative to F ss and F 0s = F fs - F ss .Phillips and Loretan (1991) and Phillips (1991) show how the triangular representation of a cointegrated system can be used to derive the asymptotic properties of the OLS estimates of the cointegration parameters. For our purposes, the most important result is that the OLS estimate of $s from (13a) is asymptotically unbiased and efficient only if u ft and u st are contemporaneously uncorrelated and there is no feedback between u ft and u st (i.e, s t is weakly exogenous for $s and u ft does not Granger cause u st and vise-versa). These correlation and feedback effects can be expressed in terms of specific components of the long-run covariance matrix of u t . The long-run covariance matrix of u t is defined as = (I - C )-1V (I - C )-1N and this matrix can be S 'j 4k '&4E [u 0u )k ]'R (1)V R (1))decomposed into S = ) + 'N where ) = '0 + ', '0 = E[u 0u 0N ] and . Let S and ''j 4k '1E [u 0u )k ]) have elements T ij and )ij (i,j = 0,s ), respectively. Using these matrices it can be shown that the elements that contribute to the bias and nonnormality of OLS estimates are the quantities 2 = T s 0/T ss and )s 0, which measure the long-run correlation and endogeneity between u ft and u st . If these elements are zero then the OLS estimates are asymptotically (mixed) normal, unbiased and efficient ing the triangular system (13) some tedious calculations show (see Zivot (1995))2 = ("s F 00/(1 - N ) + F 0,/(1 - N ))@("s ²F 00/(1 - N ) + 2"s F 0s /(1 - N ) + F ss )-1,)s 0 = "s F 00N [(1 - N )(1 - N ²)]-1 + F 0s /(1 - N ),and these quantities are zero if "s = 0 (spot rates are weakly exogenous for $s ) and F 0s = 0. In typical exchange rate data, however, F 0s . 0 and F 00 is much smaller than F ss which implies that 2 .0 and )s 0 . 0 so the OLS bias is expected to be very small.To illustrate the expected magnitude of the OLS bias we conducted a simple Monte Carlo12experiment where data was generated by (13) with $s = 1, "s = 1, -3, N = 0.9, F ss = (0.035)², F 00 =(0.001)², and D 0s = 06. When "s = 1 the FRUH is true and when "s = -3 it is not. In both cases the forward premium is highly autocorrelated. Table 2 gives the results of OLS applied to the levels regression (12a) for samples of size T =100 and T =250. In both cases the magnitude of the OLS bias is negligible. The OLS standard errors, however, are biased which cause the size distortions in the nominal 5% t -tests of the hypothesis that $s = 1.4.3 Empirical ExampleTable 3 presents estimation results for the VAR model (7) and Table 4 gives the results for the triangular model (13) imposing $s = 1 for the pound, yen and Canadian dollar monthly exchange rate series. The VAR(1) model was selected for all currencies by likelihood ratio tests for lag lengths and standard model selection criteria. For all currencies, f t and s t behave very similarly: the estimated intercepts and error variances are nearly identical and the estimated correlation between ,ft and ,st ,D fs , is 0.99. The estimated coefficients from the triangular model essentially mimic the corresponding coefficients from the VAR(1). Table 5 gives the results of Johansen’s likelihood ratio test for the number of cointegrating vectors for the three exchange rate series based on the estimation of (7). If the intercepts are restricted to the error correction term then the Johansen rank test finds one cointegrating vector in all cases. If the intercept is unrestricted then the rank tests finds that spot and forward rates for the pound and Canadian dollar are I (0). However, for each series, the likelihood ratio statistic does not reject the hypothesis that the intercepts be restricted to the error correction term. Table 5 also reports the results of the Engle-Granger (1987) two-step residual based ADF t -test for no cointegration based on estimating $s by OLS. For long lag lengths the null of no-cointegration between forward and spot rates is not rejected at the 10% level but for short lag lengths the null is rejected at the 5% level 7. Table 6 reports estimates of $s using OLS, Stock and Watson’s (1993)dynamic OLS (DOLS) and dynamic GLS (DGLS) lead-lag estimator and Johansen’s (1995) reduced rank MLE 8. The latter three estimators are asymptotically efficient estimators and yield asymptotically valid standard errors. Notice that all of the estimates of $s are extremely close to 1and the hypothesis that $s = 1 cannot be rejected using the asymptotic t-tests based on DOLS/DGLS and MLE. Table 7 shows the MLEs of the parameters of the VECM (8) where the intercepts are。