当前位置:文档之家› 孔金阳

孔金阳

孔金阳
孔金阳

DesignandImplementationofElectronicCommunities

LEVENTV.ORMAN orman@https://www.doczj.com/doc/33155542.html,

Cornell University, JohnsonGraduateSchoolof Management, Ithaca NY 14853

Abstract. Electroniccommunitiescanbedesignedtoorganizeconsumers,topooltheirpurchasingpower, andtoguidetheirpurchasingdecisions.Suchcommercialelectroniccommunitieshavethepotentialtofaci l-

itate the creation of novel marketplaces, and even radically change the buyer–seller interaction, as physical

communities did throughout the history. Commercial electronic communities are groups of consumers that

participate in the marketplace as a single unit. In addition to bargaining power gained from such bundling,

such communities can expand markets by reducing market uncertainty, and they have the potential to dras-

tically reduce transaction costs. However, these benefits are not automatic, and the optimum design and

implementation of communities are critical to their economic success. The size and the makeup of a com-

munity, the size and the nature of the product bundle it offers, and the concise description and efficient

implementation of the community as an electronic marketplace are all critical factors for the success of a

community.

Keywords:

electroniccommunities,electronicmarkets,marketdesign,marketimplementation,distributed markets

1. Electronic communities Electroniccommunitiesarevirtualgatheringplacesforpeoplesharingcommoninterests.

Bulletin boards and newsgroups were the earliest examples of virtual gathering places. Largenumbersofbulletinboardsandnewsgroupshavebeencreated,eachcharacterized

byatheme,andeachattractingusersinterestedinthattheme,andfacilitatinginteraction

and information exchange among them. Electronic communities are the current multi- mediaversionsoftheseearlyattempts,wherenotonlytextmessagesareexchanged,but photographs, audio and video files, interactive chat, conferencing, and database access

are available to community members [12]. Although communities have been studied extensively as a social phenomenon, their commercial applications have been limited

[5,12,15]. Early Internet vendors have established communities to facilitate interaction amongtheircustomers,inanefforttoengenderloyaltyandasenseofcommunityamong theircustomers,andtoengagecustomerstoextendthelengthofstayattheirsite[2,10]. Suchvendorcreatedcommunitiesareuseful,butverylimitedinscopeandfunctionality ascommercialenterprises.Theyarelimitedinscopetoonevendor’sproducts,andthey arelimitedinfunctionalitytoserveonlythecommercialinterestsofoneparticularven-

dor. More recently, buying cooperatives have been formed to pool buyers on the web to takeadvantageofvolumediscountsofferedbyvendors[2,10].Thesenewwebbusinesses

aremoreambitiousintheireffortstoorganizeconsumers,butstillfallfarshortofafullscale commercial electronic community, since membership is very ephemeral, and lim- itedtoasinglepurchasingdecisionforasinglegoodorservice.Electroniccommunities

designed to organize consumers, pool their purchasing power, and guide their purchas-

ing decisions have the potential to facilitate electronic marketplaces, and even radically

change the nature of buyer–seller interaction, as physical communities throughout the

history have often changed the nature of physical marketplaces. We will refer to such electroniccommunitiesas commercialelectroniccommunities.

Commercial electronic communities in their most general form are communities

that participate in the marketplace as a single unit. Such communities are similar to

consumer cooperatives, and they are often impractical in the physical world due to the intensiveinformationprocessingrequirementsinformingthecommunity.HealthMain-

tenance Organizations (HMO) are typical examples of commercial communities in the

physical world since the members negotiate with health care providers as a group, and

all members are entitled to all services provided by the HMO, which are bundled into themembershipprice.Suchcommunitiesaremorecosteffectiveinelectroniccommerce becauseofthereductionincommunicationandinformationprocessingcoststhatarees- sentialindesigning,forming,andoperatingacommercialelectroniccommunity,which wouldoftenbeprohibitiveinthephysicalworld.Thecriticalissuesindesigningelectronic communitiesrangefromdeterminingthefeasibilityandtheoptimumdesignofcommu-

nitiesto theimpactof such communitieson the markets andtheeconomyingeneral. Communitiescanbeviewedasbundlesofconsumers,andassuchtheyaresimilar

to bundles of goods, and their effect on the marketplace is symmetric to bundling of

goods. There is an extensive literature on bundling and its effect on the marketplace.

That literature is relevant both because of the similarities of the impact on the market, butalsoforcomparisonpurposestodeterminewhatcommunitiescanprovideaboveand

beyond bundling of goods[3,4,7,8].

2. Design issues

Community design is an interdisciplinary endeavor. Technology and economic issues areintertwinedinseparably.Theoptimumdesignrequiresacomprehensivetreatmentof bothtechnicalandeconomicissues,astheyrelatetoboththeinternalorganizationofthe communityand itsimpact on the markets [5,11].

The most fundamental problems are in the internal organization of communities,

as that defines the relationship between the community and its members. There is a

spectrum of possibilities: At one extreme, a pure community is where all members are entitledtoallgoodsandservicesprocuredbythecommunityoperator,allbundledinone

membership price. A segmented community is where members have varying privileges andentitlements,whichisequivalenttomultiplesubcommunities.Attheotherextreme,

a community where the members are only entitled to the option to acquire any of the goodsandservicesforadditionalfees,whichisequivalenttoaretailerwithmembership discountsasinshoppingcards.ApurecomDESIGNANDIMPLEMENTA TIONOFELECTRONIC COMMUNITIES 165

intensiveinformationprocessingrequirements,butquitefeasibleinelectroniccommerce

with its reduced communication andinformationprocessingcosts.

Purecommunitiesraiseanumberofdifficultorganizationalandtechnicalquestions.

The effective description of a community for the market place is the most fundamental

https://www.doczj.com/doc/33155542.html,munitiesareabstractstructures,andtheyneedtobedescribedforthemarket

place to facilitate the consumers’ decision processes to join a community. At a sim-

plistic level, they could be described as bundles of goods and services procured by the community operator in the past, and those bundles can be used as an indicator of future procurements.Themembersstayinthecommunitytotheextentthatthevaluegenerated bythecommunityoperatorjustifiestheirmembershipfees,andthevaluetheyreceiveis

higher than the value generated by competing communities plus switching costs. Such descriptions are practical, but ignore the vast potential of communities combined with abstractdescriptions.Abstractdescriptionsforabstractstructures,suchascommunities,

are likely to generate value by encouraging abstract decision making, and a significant

drop in transaction costs, above and beyond what can be achieved with bundling. The

typical examples in this area are mutual funds for investors, where the funds are de-

scribed in terms of their risk/return characteristics, not as bundles of stocks, bonds and commercial papers. Mutual funds are pure communities with abstract descriptions, and

provide a rare but almost perfect example from the physical world. Another example

of a pure community is governments at various levels. The government leadership is

elected on the basis of abstract and often philosophical descriptions, such as smaller government or environmental protection. The government then enters the marketplace andparticipatesinpurchasesonbehalfofthecitizenrythatitrepresents,andallcitizens

benefit(potentially)https://www.doczj.com/doc/33155542.html,ernmentsprovide

a second rare example of a pure commercial community. The fundamental information systemquestionishowtoeffectivelydescribecommunitiesforthemarketplace,andhow tomatchthosedescriptionstotheabstractdescriptionsofconsumers.Thematchingpro- cesscanbeautomatedasindatabasesearches,semiautomatedasintextsearchengines,

or manual as in the physical world with mutual funds, HMO’s, or governm ents. In all

cases, an effective and preferably abstract description both for the communities and for theindividualsis essential[13].

Communities are not completely independent of each other. Not only their mem-

berships may overlap, in effect creating subcommunities at the intersection, but also communitiesmaycombinetoformlargerandmoreabstractcommunities.Acommunity ofsingleparentsoftoddlerswouldbeasubcommunityofsingleparents,andthatwould beasubcommunityofparents.Acommunityofmembersbelongingtoacitygovernment arealsomembersofthecorrespondingstategovernment.Suchhierarchicalrelationships

can create a rich tapestry of abstractions and aggregations, and can lead to powerful marketmechanismsthatarequitenovel.Suchstructuresarerareinthephysicalmarkets, oreveninthecurrentelectronicmarkets,buttheyarequitecommonininformationsys-

tems in the form of database abstractions. As markets are implemented more and more aspuredatabaseapplications,andconsumersandproductsarerepresentedaselectronic

collections of data, such database constructs have immediate applications in buildingmunityisrareinthephysicalworld,duetoitsabstract market structures. All the accompanying database concepts such as inheritance

of attributes within a hierarchy, and aggregation of semantic descriptions to form more

abstract descriptions,allapplydirectlytothehierarchyofcommunities[1,11].

Communities do not exist in a vacuum, but participate in markets. The interaction

of communities with markets also raises a number of significant research issues. The mostobviousadvantageofacommunityisthatitallowsconsumerstobandtogetherand negotiateasagroup,andgainmarketpower.Inthisrespect,acommunityactsasabuying

cooperative. Moreover, a community operator who participates in the market place for

the whole community, and purchases goods and services for the whole community, can

reduce transaction costs significantly. Such reduction in transaction costs of consumers allowsthemtoengageinpricediscoveryandsearchmoreeffectively,andeliminatesthe informationasymmetrybetweenconsumersandsuppliersthathavealwayscharacterized

physical markets. Communities also benefit suppliers, since they allow the suppliers to

do more effective targeting by using community descriptions, and to do more effective andlargescalebundling,oftenacrossmultiplevendors,totakeadvantageofconditional

utilities, and cross subsidies within bundled goods. Finally, communities lead to more expanded markets, since they allow better price discrimination, although the excess

profits extracted through community-based-price-discrimination do not necessarily all

accrue tothe suppliers.

Markets themselves may need to be redesigned to accommodate communities. Communitiesarenotlikelytoreacttopriceandqualityinformationinthesamemanner

as individuals. The information needs of a community operator are much more exten-

sive and often much more formal. The databases that support markets may have to be extendedtosupportmuchmoredetailedandabstractdescriptionofgoodsandservices,

and also incorporate the descriptions of communities for possible automatic matching. Exchangemechanisms,paymentsystems,marketclearingalgorithms,trust,security,and insurancemechanismsmayallneedtobeslightlymoreformal,morecomprehensive,and moreautomatedtoaccommodatetheneedsofcommunities.Theprimaryreasonforsuch formalityisthelargesizeandvalueofeachtransaction,asopposedtosmallunitsoftrans- actionswhenthemarketiscomposedofindividuals.Advertisingandconsumerbehavior islikelytochangedrastically,becauseoftheintroductionofacommunityoperatorasan

intermediary to transactions, and as an agent of the consumer. The consumer-business interactionresemblesmoreabusiness–businessinteraction,whenacommunityisformed andthecommunity operatorintervenes asanintermediaryon behalfof thecommunity. Communities themselves create new types of markets, where the consumers can shopforcommunities,findcommunitiesthatbestmatchtheirneeds,andbecomemem-

bers.Thestructureofsuchsecondarymarketsisadifficultresearchissue,anditishighly intertwinedwiththesemanticdescriptionofcommunitiesexplainedaboveasatechnical researchissue.Membershippricingandcrosssubsidieswithinthecommunityaremore advancedissuesthatrequireasaprerequisitetheresolutionofcommunitydescriptionand communitysearchissues.Whyandhowanindividualbecomesamemberwilldetermine hiswillingness to pay for membershipandstaya member. DESIGNANDIMPLEMENTATIONOFELECTRONIC COMMUNITIES 167

3. Bargainingpower

Communities can have economic benefits both for consumers and for businesses. The obviousbenefittoconsumersisthenegotiatingpowergainedbypoolingtheirpurchasing

power.Theobviousbenefittothevendorsisawelldescribedandfocusedmarketthatis availableforprecisetargeting.Theadvantagetobothpartiesisasignificantreductionin

transaction costs, due to bulk purchasing for the whole community, and better-targeted marketing. A less intuitive advantage of communities is their ability to expand markets andgenerateasurplusaboveandbeyondwhatcouldbeachievedwithoutcommunities. Suchaneconomicsurpluscanmakeallpartiesbetteroff,providingastrongjustification

forthe creation ofcommunities.

However,aneconomicjustificationforcommunitiesdoesnotrequireforallparties

tobebetteroff,butonlythecommunityitself.Acommunityorganizercanformacom- munityasaseparateeconomicentitythatentersthemarketplaceonbehalfofitsmembers. Suchacommunitywouldbeeconomicallyfeasibletotheextentthatitcanextractasur-

plus for the community from the marketplace. That surplus can be viewed as additional consumersurplusforthecommunitymembers,orasprofitsforthecommunityoperator, oracombinationofboth,dependingonthenatureofthecommunity.Thatsurpluscanbe aportionoftheeconomicsurplusgeneratedbythecommunity,leavingtheremainderof

the surplus for the suppliers, making all parties better off. Alternatively, the community

surplus may be extracted from the suppliers’ profits, by using the increasing bargain-

ing power of the consumers in the community, leaving the suppliers worse off. Either possibility, or a combination ofthetwoleads toaneconomicallyfeasiblecommunity. Considerapopulationof4consumers,andamonopolistsupplierofasinglegood.

Let the reservation prices of the consumers for the good be 4, 7, 8, and 9 respectively,

and the marginal cost of producing the good is 2/unit. The optimum price set by the

monopolist will be 7, with a total profit of 15, and a total consumer surplus of 3, as

shownin figure1. Nowconsiderapairwisegroupingoftheseconsumersintotwocommunities,with

reservationprices4+7 = 11,and8+9 = 17.Eachcommunityconsistsof2consumers

and will buy a package of 2 units of the good, if its price is below its reserFigure2. The total profit and the total consumer surplus for 2 communities with reservation prices 11 and

17, and amonopolist supplier ofa good with marginal cost of4.

or it will buy none. The marginal cost of a two-unit package is 2*2 = 4. The optimum pricesetbythemonopolistforatwo-unitpackageis11,thetotalprofitsare14,andthe

total consumer surplusis 6, as shown infigure2.

Clearly, the communities, by using their bargaining power, extracted additional

surplus, raising it from 3 to 6, at the expense of the supplier, whose profits fell from

15 to 14. The community accomplished this by pressuring the supplier to lower its unit

price from 7 to 11/2 = 5.5, as a direct result of bargaining power gained by forming a community.

The additional consumer surplus is not necessarily achieved at the expense of https://www.doczj.com/doc/33155542.html,munitiescanexpandmarkets,andgeneratesurplusthatcanbenefit

all.Bothconsumersandsupplierscanbebetteroffasaresultofcommunities.Consider

a different pairwise grouping of the four consumers into two new communities, with reservation prices of 4 + 8 = 12, and 7 + 9 = 16. The marginal cost of a two-unit

package is still 4. The optimum price set by the seller will be 12, with a total profit of

16, and thetotal consumer surpluswillbe4,asshowninfigure3.

Clearly, these communities generated enough surplus to make both parties better

off.Theseller’sprofitswentupfrom15to16,andthetotalconsumersurplusrosefrom

3to4. The communities accomplished this by expanding the market, and generating

additional economic surplus for alltoshare.vation price, DESIGNANDIMPLEMENTATIONOFELECTRONIC COMMUNITIES 169

Figure4.

Profitasafunctionofpriceandmarketvariance,whichsummarizestheproblemfacedbysuppliers.

Not all communities are beneficial. Some communities do not benefit the con-

sumers,andhencetheyarenoteconomicallyviable,sincetheconsumershavenoincen-

tive to join them. Consider, a third possible pairwise grouping of these consumers into twocommunitieswithreservationprices4+9 = 13,and7+8 = 15.Themarginalcost

of a two-unit package is still 4. The optimum price for the seller will be 13, with total

profitsof18,andatotal consumer surplusof2,asshowninfigure4.

Clearly,theconsumersurplusislowerthantheopenmarket,sinceitwentdownfrom

3to2.Consequently,thesecommunitiesarenoteconomicallyfeasible,sinceconsumers havenoincentivetojointhem.Thecriticalquestionforacommunityoperatorishowto determinetheoptimumcommunity,andtodesignittomaximizethecommunitysurplus. Thecriticalvariableisthevarianceofreservationprices,ormarketuncertainty.Itis nosurprisethatasthevariancedecreases,thesupplier’sprof itsgoupbecauseofbettertar- getedpricing,andconsumersurplusfalls.However,thatisnotuniformlyso.Atveryhigh

variances,thetrendcanreverseitself,themarketcanshrinkconsiderablybydraggingthe

consumer surplus down, and the suppliers may take advantage of the shrinking market byconcentratingon thehighendcustomers,andcanactuallyincreasetheirprofits.The

basic economic problem is a game theoretic problem. The suppliers control prices and setthemoptimallytomaximizeprofits,andcommunitiescontrolmarketuncertaintyand

setthem optimallybydesigningtheircommunitiestomaximizetheirsurplus.Suppliers’problemistosetthepricesoptimallyforagivenmarketvariancecreatedbycommunities. Thecommunities’problemistosetthemarketuncertaintyoptimallybydesigningtheir communitiesgiventheassumptionthatthesupplierswillrespondbysettingpricesopti-

mally.Givenauniformdistributionofreservationprices,simulationsusingMathematica

software show that profit is a unimodal function of price, for each market variance, and

the optimum price decreases as the market variance increases. Figure 4 summarizes the

problem facedbythesuppliers.

Similarly,theconsumersurplusisaunimodalfunctionofmarketvarianceassuming anoptimalsettingofpricesbysuppliers.Acommunityoperator’sproblemistodesignthe optimumcommunitythatmaximizesthecommunitysurplus,bycomputingtheoptimum

point v,as shown in figure 5. 170 ORMAN

Figure5. Theeffect of marketuncertainty on thesupplierprofits and community surplus.

4. Transactioncost Economicviabilityofacommunitydoesnotrequireamonopolistselleragainstwhicha communitycanexercisebargainingpower.Acommunitycanbeviableeveninacompet- itiveenvironment,withcompetitiveprices.Inacompetitiveenvironment,evenwhenthe

bargaining power is not a relevant issue, a community can produce significant surplus

through savings in transaction costs. Savings in transaction costs can be considerable

since the members of the community do not have to engage in market transactions in- dividually, but the community operator executes market transactions on behalf of all members. Such a community would be able to reduce transaction costs in proportion

to the size of the community since the community operator would develop expertise,

perform the search for goods, and execute each transaction only once on behalf of all members.Moreover,thecommunityoperatorwouldbundleanumberofproductsthatare

relevant to the community, and further reduce transaction costs by developing expertise

in a line of products, and by using the expertise developed in one product in acquiring

other similarproducts.

Economic viability of a community does not require the community to be an or- ganicstructureemergingspontaneously.Acommunitycanbecreatedasanindependent businessbyacommunityoperator.Thecommunityoperator’sobjectiveistodesignthe optimumcommunitytomaximizeitsprofit.Thecommu nityoperator’sprofitisaportion ofthesurplusgeneratedbythecommunity,whichwasdiscussedintheprevioussection.

The community operator’s profit is determined by the revenues r from members in the formofmembershipfees,thepaymentsc tosuppliersforthegoods,andthetransaction

costs t: p = r -c -t.Ina competitive environment, since the cost of goods is exoge-

nous,andalsothetransactioncostsareindependentofsize,thena¨?vecommunitydesign

would aim for the largest possible community, to maximize revenues, and to amortize

the transaction costs over the largest possible membership base. In fact, the largest pos- siblecommuntiyisrarelytheoptimum,becausethesizeimpactsthecompositionofthe

community.Acommunitydoesnotchooseitsmembersrandomly,butselectsthosethat aremostrelevanttothethemeofthecommunity,orinotherwords,thosewhoarewilling topaythemostforthegoodsandservicesofferedbythecommunity.ConseDESIGNANDIMPLEMENTA TIONOFELECTRONIC COMMUNITIES 171

effective reservation price of the community members decreases as the community size increases, since the community has to accept lower paying members to the community. Themembershipfeesaredeterminedbythereservationpriceofthelowestpayingmem- bersofthecommunity,sinceotherwisethosenewestmembersofthecommunitywould

not join. Even a price discrimination scheme, such as the subsidy system discussed in

Section 3 would result in a reduction of the average reservation price of the commu-

nity as the commmunity size increases, and lower paying members are admitted. This fundamental problem with size is a direct result of the increasing heterogeneity of the community with increasing size. Consequently, the optimum community size is deter-

mined by a trade off between the larger savings from transaction costs, and the smaller revenuesfrom amoreheterogeneouscommunity,asthecommunity sizeincreases. Considerfourconsumerswithreservationprices4,7,8,and9forasingleproduct whoseacquisitioncosttothecommunityis2perunit,andthetransactioncostis6.The

community operator tries to set the membership fee optimally, which determines the

optimum community size by admitting all those whose reservation prices are above the membership fee. The optimum membership fee for this community would be 7, with communitysize 3 as showninthetable below.

Membership fee community size revenues cost ofgoods transaction cost profit.

4416 86 2

73 21 6 6 9 (optimum)

8216 46 6

91 926 1

Now consider the same four consumers with two products. The reservation prices

are 4, 7, 8, and 9 for the first product, and 2, 2, 4, and 8 for the second, and the total reservationpricesforthebundleare6,9,12,17.Thecostofacquiringthethebundleis assumedtobe4,andthetransactioncostremains6.Theoptimumcommunitymember-

ship fee will be 12 with the resulting community size 2 for the bundle size 2, as shown in the table below.

Membership fee community size revenues cost ofgoods transaction cost profit.

6424 16 6 2

9327 12 6 9

12 2 24 8 6 10 (optimum)

17 1 17 4 6 7

Finally, consider the same consumers with a bundle of three products, where the reservation prices are 4, 7, 8, 9 for the first, 2, 2, 4, 8 for the second, and 0, 1, 2, 6 for thethird,withtotalsof6,10,14,23.Thecostofthebundleis6,andthet172 ORMAN

remains6.Theoptimumcommunitymembershipfeewillbe23withcommunitysize1

forthe bundle size3, asshown in thefollowing table:

Membership fee community size revenues cost ofgoods transaction cost profit.

6424 24 6 –6

10 3 30 186 6

14 2 28 126 10

23 1 23 6 6 11 (optimum) Itisnotacoincidencethatthereisaninverserelationshipbetweenthecommunity

size and the bundle size for the optimum communities. Intuitively, this result follows fromtheexistenceofanoptimumheterogeneitywithinacommunity.Thatheterogeneity

or variance within a community can be achieved by increasing the community size or thebundlesize,orinotherwordsincreasingonerequiresdecreasingtheothertostayat theoptimumlevelofvariance.Anotherintuitiveexplanationisthetendencyofbundling toreducethevarianceofreservationpricesoverthewholepopulation,andclusterthem around the mean. This observation follows immediately from the central limit theorem. However,areductioninvarianceforthewholepopulationactuallyincreasesthevariance ifwerestrictourselvesonlytothetailsofthedistribution.Sincethecommunitydoesnot select its members randomly, but specifically from the upper tail of the distribution, it facesincreasingvariancewithbundling.Consequently,increasingbundlesizeleadstoa sharperdropinmembers’willingnesstopayasthecommunitysizeincreases,andhence

the optimum community size becomes smaller. We will now develop these arguments moreformally.

Let p be the profits, r revenues, c the cost of goods, and t is the transaction cost.

p = r -c -t.Revenues are dependent on the membership price l and the size of the community s: r = ls. The membership price l is the lowest reservation price among members per product in the bundle, and it is determined by the community size s and the bundle size b. The decision variables for a community organizer are the community

size and the product bundle, and the membership price l is set at a level to attract that

size community to that bundle. For a small community with a small product bundle,

the membership price can be set high to attract only those that are most interested in thatproductbundle.Asthesizeofthecommunitygrows,thecommunitybecomesmore heterogeneous, and to attract lower paying members, the community has to lower its membership fee. However, the drop in membership fees are the steepest for smaller communities, and as the community grows the highest paying members are exhausted, 2 2

and the rate of drop flattens out. Consequently, ?l/?s = l < 0 and ? l/?s = l > 0.

Similarly,asthebundlesizebgrows,thereservationpriceforthebundlegrowssincethe valueofallitemsareassumedtobenonzero,butthegrowthrateisslowerasthebundle

grows, and the most desirable items for the community are exhausted. Consequently,

* 2 2 **

?l/?b = l > 0and? l/?b = l < 0.Onthecostside,normalizingcostswithrespect

to reservation prices eliminates the variance of absolute cost values, and we can safelyransactioncostquently,theDESIGNANDIMPLEMENTATIONOFELECTRONIC COMMUNITIES 173

assume that the cost of a bundle increases with the size of the bundle at a constant rate,

* 2 2 **

?c/?b = c > 0and? c/?b = c = 0, but the bundle cost is independent of the 2 2 communitysize,?c/?s = c = 0and? c/?l = l = 0.

Weknowfromdefinitionsthat p = ls-cs-t,andthecommunityoperatorneeds

to maximize profit p with respect to community size s and the bundle size b, resulting

in: p = l +l s -c-c s = 0whichimpliesthatl s = c-l istheoptimalitycondition

since p = l +l s +l -c -c s -c < 0forsmalls fromtheassumptionsabove.

* * * * *

Similarly, p = l s-c s = 0impliesthatl = c istheoptimalityconditionsince

** ** ** ** **

p = l s -c s < 0sincel < 0andc = 0fromassumptionsabove.

The two optimality conditions can be used to derive the optimum community size andtheoptimum bundlesize asshown graphicallyinfigure 6. Therecanbemultipleoptimumsolutions,sincecostisnotnecessarilyalinearfunc- tionofthebundlesize.Whentherearemultiplesolutions,thereisaninverserelationship

betweenthe bundle sizeand the communitysize alongtheefficientfrontier. *

The preceding analysis depends heavily on the computation of l and l , the price sensitivityofthecommunitywithrespecttocommunitysizeandthebundlesize.These

* *

Figure6. l = c condition is used to compute the optimum bundle size b1 in the first graph, and then l s = c - l condition is used in the second graph to compute the optimum community size s1 and the

optimum community membership feel1 fromthe given bundlecost c and bundle size b1.

Figure7. Theinverserelationshipbetweencommunitysizes andthebundlesizebisderivedwherethebold * *

arrow shows the increasing b values, and the bold curve shows the efficient frontier where l = c . These

curves follow from the assumption that the willingness to pay increases slower than the bundle cost as the

bundle size increases since communities select themostpreferreditems first for the bundle. variablescanbeestimatedfromthesizeofthepopulationbasesupportingacommunity

and the size of the product bundle relevant to that population base. In other words, the

ultimate potential size of the community, and the ultimate potential size of the product

bundle can be used. Assuming a uniform distribution of reservation prices within the

population allows reasonable estimates of the price sensitivity as the community size

and/orthebundlesizegrows.Potentialpopulationbaseismucheasiertoestimate.Some communitieshaveaverylargepopulationbase,butduetononcommercialnatureofthose communities, the potentially relevant product base is relatively small. A community of Catholics for example draws from a very large population base, but the product bundle designedspecificallyforCatholicsmaynotbeverylarge,becauseofthenoncommercial

nature of the community. A community of golfers or a community of young parents

on the other hand, may have a much larger potentially relevant product base. When the population base of a community or the potentially relevant product base is large, the

community is less price sensitive with respect to that variable, since there is a bigger

pool to exploit before the reservation prices drop significantly. The assumption of uni-

form distribution of reservation prices makes estimation of price sensitivity relatively

easy.

5. Implementation

A marketplace for communities and bundles is fundamentally different from markets thatsupport individual transactions. Thereare threemajorissues:

a. The design ofthe communities and theproduct bundlesas elaboratedinSection4.

b. The description and marketing of communities where individual consumers can find communities, evaluate their relevancetotheirneeds, andjointhem.

c. The description and marketing of product bundles where communities and product bundlescan find eachother,evaluatealternatives, andengagein transactions.

We have discussed the community design problem in considerable detail in this article. Thedesignofmarketplacesforproductbundles,andthepricingmechanismsforbundles haveattractedsomeattentioninrecentliterature[3,4,6–8].Marketshavebeendesigned

where static or dynamic pricing can be used to buy and sell bundles of goods. Bundle

markets are considerably more complex than individual item markets, since a bundle transactionisnotsimplyacollectionofindividualitemtransactions,butitisacollection ofconditionaltransactions.Eachtransactiontakesplaceconditionallydependingonthe successofothertransactions,sinceeitherthewholebundleisexchangedornoexchange

takesplace.Thedesignandimplementationofsuchmarketshavebeenstudiedelsewhere,

but has a direct impact on the interaction of communities and their respective product

bundles[6,7].

The remaining issue for the successful creation of communities is the description andmarketingofcommunitiestoconsumers.AcommunityisanabstractstrucDESIGNANDIMPLEME NTATIONOFELECTRONIC COMMUNITIES 175

requires an abstract description for the market place. There are three possible tools to

describe acommunity.

a. Itcanbedescribedasacollectionofproducts,i.e.aproductbundle.Thebundlemay befixedoritmayvaryovertime.Afixedbundlecancompletelydescribeacommunity asamereprocurerofthatbundle.Thisisthesimplestpossiblecommunity,although

the description may be tedious and difficult to process if a large number of products areinvolved.Ifthebundleisvariable,atentativeoracurrentbundlecanbeprovided, anditisusednotonlyasadescriptionofthecommunityasitstandsnow,butalsoasa predictoroffutureproductbundlestobedeliveredbythecommunity.Inthatrespect,a bundledescriptionissimilartoasubscriptionwherethefuturebundlesarepredicted

from the current bundle. A bundle of household appliances for example may be a fixedbundleofferedbythecommunitytoallmembers,oritmaybeavariablebundle

including service and future replacements. In the latter case, the future replacements

are predicted from the current bundle offered, and the community can also make

prediction easierbyprovidingservicecontractsandguarantees.

b. Acommunitycanbedescribedbyalistofdesiredmemberattributes.Suchanabstract descriptionwouldbeeasiertoprocessbyprospectivemembers,butitwouldalsoentail

more uncertainty, since the matching of member attributes to product bundles is not

a trivial process. A communit y of “single parents” for example would be relatively

easy to describe and market, and the prospective members would easily understand therelevantaudienceforthecommunity.However,therelevantproductbundlewould

be difficult to predict by relyingsolelyonthedescription ofmember attributes.

c. An effective third solution may be a combination of the last two approaches. An ab- stractdescriptionintermsofmemberattributescanbeusedasahighleveldescription ofacommunity,butthedescriptioncanbesupplementedwithadescriptionofproduct bundlesthathavebeendeliveredtothemembersinthepasttoreducetheuncertainty aboutthecommunity’sproductbundle.A“Singleparentsofinfants”communitythat

also lists as a product bundle “baby sitting services”, “easy to prepare baby foods”,

and “home delivered baby clothes” would be an example of a community using an

effective combinationof the twodescriptivetechniques.

Finally, a marketplace needs to provide a search mechanism for consumers to locate relevantcommunities,compareandcontrastthem,andevaluatethemforpossiblemem-

bership. The distributed nature of the modern electronic markets requires description techniquesthatareuniversal,extensible,andcompatiblewithavarietyofexistinginter-

nal systems. XML emerged as a standard for data description in this highly distributed

and diverse environment [1,14,16]. Although XML was designed to describe raw data

in terms of individual data attributes, its hierarchical structure is suitable for describing aggregatesandabstractionswithminormodifications,andthoseaggregatesandabstrac-

tions are the most critical tools for communities. A product bundle for example can be describedsimplybyadescriptivenametaggedasa,andasaproductlistenu- meratedanddescribedashierarchicalsubcomponentsofthebundle.Individualproductstcan further be broken down to components for descriptive purposes. Communities can

also be described in a similar fashion, by a descriptive name tagged as , andthentheindividualscomprisingthecommunitylistedanddescribedasitshierarchi- calsubcomponents.Thecharacteristicsdescribingcommunitiessuchasthedemographic

and psychographic attributes can be attached to the community entity as its attributes,

asdistinctfromtheattributesofindividuals.XML’shierarchicalstructurelendsitselfto

such a distinction between aggregates and its components, although XML does not au- tomatically provide a means of inheritance of attributes from communities to members. Inheritancecanbeaccomplishedhowevereitheratthequerylevel,orwithminorexten-

sions to XML, as we will argue later. The description problem becomes more complex whenacombinationofproductbundlesandmembercharacteristicsareusedtodescribe communities, especially when product bundles and member characteristics vary over

time. XML has neither the tools to distinguish between different types of descriptions,

nor the features to represent time and historical data [1,14]. However, all of these prob- lemscanbeovercomewithminoradjustments,orbycreativeuseoftags[9].Considera

community of single parents of infants. It can be represented as an XML data structure withtherootsingleparentsofinfants,withvariousattributesattachedto

the community, such as none, 0–2, etc. Similarly, theproducts ofthe communitycan be listed in ahierarchical structure

...

...

.....

....

with appropriate attributes attached to each, and possibly more subcomponents. There areseveral fundamental shortcomings.

a. There is no feature to link community attributes such as https://www.doczj.com/doc/33155542.html,munityattributes

such as age range act as integrity constraints on the individual attributes, and those integrityconstraintshavetobeimplementedseparatelyandtheirsemanticshavetobe builtintotheapplicationsoftware.XMLdoesnotprovideadvanceddatabasefeatures

suchas integrity constraints[1,9].

b. Although product attributes can be listed simply as XML attributes, there are no

standards for describing various product categories, and the descriptions and tags

used by one community may not be compatible with the descriptions and tags used

byothers.SuchsemanticinconsistencyisamajorproblemwithXMLwhichdoesnot

employ universal schemas, however there is considerable activity by many industry

groupsto develop industrystandards forproductdescriptions [14].ure,andc. There is a fundamental difficulty of linking various community characteristics to

product attributes. This is a major theoretical problem in understanding how certain consumercharacteristicsrelatetocertainproductcharacteristicsintermsofmatching andmeetingthoseneeds.Itisalsoamajortechnicalproblemofhowtorepresentthose semanticrelationshipsbetweenconsumerattributesandmatchingproductattributes.

XML is not a semantic modeling tool, and complex relationships among entities

cannot be represented without resorting to artificial constructs such as proxies and

duplicates [1]. Consequently, establishing relationships between communities and productscannoteasilybeautomatedeitherattheanalyticaloratthetechnicallevels, andwewillleavethemasmanualprocesses.Thedevelopmentofappropriateproduct

bundles for each community, and the description of those bundles in terms of their relationshiptocommunityattributesareleftasmanualprocessestobecarriedoutby communityoperators as part of the communitydesignprocess.

The community design, the identification of relevant product bundles, and effective de- scriptionandmarketingofthecommunityanditsproductbundlearecomplexprocesses,

especially when one considers the number of all possible communities and all possible productbundles,evenforanarrowlyspecifiedniche.Theproblemisexponentiallymore

complex than matching individual consumers and individual products, since the num-

ber of all possible communities and the number of all possible bundles are exponential

functions of the number of individual consumers and individual products respectively. However,thiscombinatorialproblemcanbesimplifiedconsiderablybyconsideringnatu- rallyhierarchicalstructureofcommunitiesandbundles,andusinginheritancetechniques

to reuse community attributes and product bundles. A simple example is a hierarchy of communities:

Sinceasingleparentisaspecializationofaparent,theattributes,descriptions,andprod- uctbundlesofparentscommunitycanbeinheritedbysingleparentscommunity.Sucha hierarchicalstructureamongcommunitiescansignificantlysimplifycommunitydesign andproductselectionsincetheexpertisedevelopedwithinacommunitycanbeinherited

and easily reused in all of its subcommunities. If the operator of the parents commu- nityspecializedinproductsandservicesrelevanttoallparents,andmakethatexpertise

available to its subcommunities, then the development of a single parents community

would be significantly simplified allowing the operator of that community to specialize intheproductsandservicesrelevantonlytothatsubsegment.Similarly,attheindividual memberlevel,allmembersofthesingleparentscommunityareautomaticallymembers oftheparentscommunity,therebypopulatingtheparentscommunity,andautomatically inheritingtheattributesandbundlesrelevanttoparents,significantlyincreasingthesize oftheproductbundleavailabletothem.Suchinheritanceandaggregationarenotreadily availableintheXMLtoolset.Consequently,asearchforcommunitiesforsingleparents would not automatically include information about its supercommunities, such as the

parents community, nor would it include in its product bundle all the products inher-

ited from its supercommunities. To accommodate these features, XML descriptions of communities would have to be expanded to include attributes that explicitly list all of itssupercommunities.Atypicalexamplewouldusethetagtofully

describe the singleparentscommunity.

single-parents ......

parents ......

singles ...

people...

A search for all supercommunites of a community and their product bundles would

require a recursive search, and once again XML query languages such as XML QL do notprovidegeneralrecursion.OnceagainXMLhastobeextendedtoaccommodatesuch

searches for communities. One possibility is using Extended Stylesheet language XSL whichdoesprovideforlimitedrecursion.WithoutgettingintodetailsofXSL,itsuffices

to point out that XSL provides templates that are used to search for all data that fit the template.TemplatesarepathsonXMLhierarchies,andallpathsthatfitthetemplateare

returned.Specifically,XSLprovidesforwildcardoption*thatfitsallsubpaths,andthat optioncanbeusedforlimitedrecursionontheXMLhierarchies.Inourexample,tofind

all supercommunities of the single parents community would require a template path thatstartsatsingleparentsandendatasupercommunitybutwouldallowanynumberof supercommunities in between. That template would return all supercommunities of the

single parentscommunity,as shown below:

Similarly,aggregateproductbundlesofallsupercommunitiescanbeobtainedbyanXSL

query with the following templates where the first tempate returns the products of the singleparentscommunity,andthesecondreturnstheproductsofallofitssupercommu-

nities:

/

6. Conclusions

Electronic communities have the potential to organize consumers in novel ways and to

create new marketplaces. There are significant benefits to communities such as the in- creasingbargainingpowerforconsumers,andthereductionoftransactioncostsforboth

consumers and suppliers. However, these benefits are not automatic, and the optimum DESIGNANDIMPLEMENTATIONOFELECTRONIC COMMUNITIES 179

design and implementation of communities are critical to their commercial success. Randomcollectionsofconsumersarenotlikelytobeeconomicallyviablecommunities; theywouldbedifficulttodescribetothemarketplaceandattractnewmembers;andthey wouldbedifficulttoimplementinadistributedenvironmentwhereaconciseandconsis-

tent description of the community to all constituencies is important. Successful design

requires a careful computation of the optimum community: its desired membership, its optimumsize,andtheproductbundleofferedtoit.Italsorequiresanabstractdescription

of the community in terms of product bundles and member attributes, and even possi-

bly their time dependence. New XML tools are needed to describe such aggregates and abstractionstoallow communities to participateindistributed electronicmarkets.

References

[1] S. Abiteboul, P.Buneman andD. Suciu,Data on theWeb(Morgan Kaufmann 2000).

[2] A. Armstrong and J. Hagel, The Real Value of Online Communities (Harvard Business Review, May

1996).

[3] Y. Bakos and E. Brynjolfsson, Bundling and competition on the Internet: Aggregation strategies for

information goods, Marketing Science 19(1)(2000)63–82.

[4]

Y.BakosandE.Brynjolfsson,Bundlinginformationgoods:Pricing,profitsandefficiency,Management Science 45(12)(1999) 1613–1630.

[5] S. Balasubramanian and V. Mahajan, Economic leverage of virtual community, International Journal

of Electronic Commerce 5(3) (2001)103–138.

[6] M.Fan,S.Srinivasan,J.StallaertandA.B.Whinston,ElectronicCommerceandtheRevolutioninthe Financial Markets(Thomson Learning, 2002).

[7] M. Fan, J. Stallaert and A.B. Whinston, The design and development of a financial cybermarket with

abundle tradingmechanism, International Journal of Electronic Commerce 4(1) (1999) 5–22.

[8] W.Hanson and K. Martin, Optimal bundle pricing, Management Science 32(2) (1990).

[9]

A.KumarandJ.L.Zhao,Dynamicroutingandoperationalintegritycontrolsinaworkflowmanagement system,Management Science 45(2)(1999)253–272.

[10] W.Mougayar,Opening Digital Markets(McGrawHill, 1998).

[11] L. Orman, Electronic markets, hierarchies, hubs, and intermediaries, Information Systems Frontiers

4(2) (2002) 207–222.

[12]

H.Rheingold,TheVirtualCommunity:HomesteadingtheElectronicFrontier(AddisonWesley,Read- ingMA, 1993).

[13]

B.Schmid,Requirementforelectronicmarketarchitectures,InternationalJournalofElectronicCom- merce7(1)(1997)3–6.

[14] G.P. Schneider and J.T. Perry,ElectronicCommerce(Thomson Learning, 2001).

[15] G.D. Suttles,The SocialConstruction of Communities(Universityof ChicagoPress, 1972).

[16] M.P. Van der Aalst, Process oriented architectures for electronic commerce and interorganizational

workflow,Information Systems 24(8)(1999)639–671.

相关主题
文本预览
相关文档 最新文档