Where are the speculative bubbles in US housing markets_
- 格式:pdf
- 大小:286.14 KB
- 文档页数:21
Question 1The Bretton Woods system of adjustable exchange rates effectively collapsed on August 15, 1971 when President Nixon ended the convertibility between U.S. dollars and gold. In the same announcement, Nixon also imposed a 90-day freeze on wages and prices, and imposed a 10 percent import surcharge. There was not much shedding of tears for the demise of the Bretton Woods system of adjustable peg.1971年,8月15日可调整汇率的布雷顿森林体系实际上已崩溃,尼克松总统宣布美元和黄金之间的兑换已结束。
在同一份公告中,尼克松还实行了90天的冻结工资和价格,并征收10%的进口附加税。
对可调整钉住汇率的布雷顿森林体系的消亡没有多少人遗憾。
A. Please explain:Why was there little regret amongst observers about the termination of this international monetary system. Was the lack of regret based on sound analyses?为什么观察员对于这种国际货币体系的终止没表示遗憾。
基于合理的分析是不是缺乏遗憾?Why was this particular combination of policies (wage-price controls, protectionism, and delinking gold and dollar) adopted by the US?美国为什么实施这个特殊的策略组合政策(工资- 价格控制,保护主义,黄金和美元脱钩)?What are some of the major problems that are present both in the failed Bretton Woods system, and in today's non-system of managed floating (where each country can adopt whatever exchange rate arrangement that it deems to be most advantageous to itself)?布雷顿森林体系失败的主要问题有哪些?,以及现在执行的管理的浮动汇率非系统体系存在哪些问题(每个国家可以采取有管理的浮动汇率安排,它认为对自己最有利于)?B. Please discuss the difficulties of identifying destablising speculation (speculative bubbles) in the foreign exchange market.B.请讨论在外汇市场上做投机(投机性泡沫)的困难与不稳定性。
潜在的风险隐患英语作文Title: Unveiling Potential Risks and Hazards: A Comprehensive Analysis。
In today's dynamic and interconnected world,identifying and addressing potential risks and hazards has become imperative. Whether in personal life, business endeavors, or societal structures, understanding thelurking dangers is crucial for mitigating their impacts. This essay delves into various realms to explore potential risks and hazards, offering insights into their nature, impacts, and strategies for management.1. Technological Sphere:Technology, while offering numerous benefits, also harbors significant risks. Cybersecurity breaches, data leaks, and technological failures pose threats to individuals, organizations, and even nations. With therapid advancement of artificial intelligence and automation,concerns about job displacement and ethical dilemmas emerge. Moreover, reliance on interconnected systems increases vulnerability to cascading failures, as seen in cyber-attacks on critical infrastructure.2. Environmental Domain:Climate change stands as one of the most pressing global risks. Rising temperatures, extreme weather events, and environmental degradation threaten ecosystems, livelihoods, and food security. Additionally, pollution, deforestation, and loss of biodiversity exacerbate these challenges. Failure to address these environmental risks could lead to irreversible consequences for future generations.3. Economic Landscape:Financial markets are susceptible to various risks, including market volatility, economic recessions, and systemic failures. Speculative bubbles, excessive debt, and geopolitical tensions further destabilize economies.Moreover, globalization has interconnected financial systems, amplifying the spread of financial crises across borders. Inadequate regulatory frameworks and unethical practices exacerbate these vulnerabilities.4. Health and Well-being:Health risks, both infectious and non-communicable, continue to threaten global populations. Pandemics, such as the recent COVID-19 outbreak, highlight the rapid spread and devastating impacts of infectious diseases. Additionally, lifestyle-related factors, such as poor diet, sedentary behavior, and substance abuse, contribute to the burden of non-communicable diseases. Inadequate healthcare infrastructure and disparities in access exacerbate these health risks.5. Social Dynamics:Societal risks stem from various sources, including social inequality, political instability, and cultural tensions. Disparities in wealth distribution,discrimination, and social exclusion undermine social cohesion and stability. Moreover, polarization, misinformation, and ideological extremism fuel societal divisions and undermine democratic institutions. Addressing these risks requires fostering inclusive societies and promoting social justice.6. Geopolitical Realities:Geopolitical risks encompass a range of factors, including geopolitical conflicts, terrorism, and geopolitical shifts. Regional tensions, territorial disputes, and arms proliferation threaten peace andstability in various regions. Moreover, emerging geopolitical powers and shifts in alliances reshape global power dynamics, creating uncertainty and volatility. Diplomatic efforts and multilateral cooperation are essential for managing these geopolitical risks.7. Ethical Considerations:Ethical risks arise from ethical dilemmas andmisconduct in various domains, including business, science, and governance. Corporate scandals, unethical research practices, and political corruption erode trust and integrity in institutions. Moreover, advances in technology raise ethical questions regarding privacy, autonomy, and the responsible use of emerging technologies. Upholding ethical principles and promoting transparency are essential for mitigating ethical risks.In conclusion, identifying and addressing potential risks and hazards is paramount in safeguarding individuals, organizations, and societies. By understanding the multifaceted nature of risks across different domains, proactive measures can be taken to mitigate their impacts. Collaboration between stakeholders, informed decision-making, and continuous monitoring are essential for effectively managing risks and building resilient systems for the future.。
中英文对照翻译Margin Trading Bans in Experimental Asset MarketsAbstractIn financial markets, professional traders leverage their trades because it allows to trade larger positions with less margin. Violating margin requirements, however, triggers a margin call and open positions are automatically covered until requirements are met again. What impact does margin trading have on the price process and on liquidity in financial asset markets? Since empirical evidence is mixed, we consider this question using experimental asset markets. Starting from an empirically relevant situation where margin purchasing and short selling is permitted, we ban margin purchases and/or short sales using a 2x2 factorial design to a allow for a comparative static analysis. Our results indicate that a ban on margin purchases fosters efficient pricing by narrowing price deviations from fundamental value accompanied with lower volatility and a smaller bid-ask-spread. A ban on short sales, however, tends to distort efficient pricing by widening price deviations accompanied with higher volatility and a large spread.Keywords: margin trading, Asset Market, Price Bubble, Experimental Finance1.IntroductionHowever, regulators can only have a positive impact on the life-cycle of a bubble, if they know how institutional changes affect prices in financial markets. Note that regulation is a double-edged sword since decision errors may lead from bad to worse. Given the systemic risk posed by speculative bubbles and their long history, it may be surprising how little attention bubbles have received in the literature and how little understood they are. This ignorance is partly due to the complex psychological nature of speculative bubbles but also due to the fact that the conventional financial economic theory has ignored the existence of bubbles for a long-time. But even if theories on bubble cycles have empirical relevance, it is clear that the issues surrounding the formation and the bursting of bubbles cannot be analyzed with pencil and paper. Conclusions on bubble cycles must be backed with quantitative data analysis. Given the limited number of observed empirical market crashes and their non-recurring nature, an experimental analysis of bubble formation involving controlled and replicable laboratory conditions seems to be a promising way to proceed.The paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews the related literature, Section 0 presents the details of the experimental design and section IV reports the data analysis. In section V, we summarize our findings and provide concluding remarks.2. Leverage in asset marketsDo margin requirements have any effects on market prices? Fisher (1933) and also Snyder (1930) mentioned the importance of margin debt in generating price bubbles when analyzing the Great Crash of 1929. The ability to leverage purchases lead to a higher demand, ending up in inflated prices. The subsequently appreciated collateral allowed to leverage purchases even more. This upward price spiral was fueled by an expansion of debt. From the end of 1924, brokers’loans rose four and one-half times (by $6.5 billion) and in the final phase broker’s borrowings rose at more than 100% a year until the bubble crashed. Then, after the peak of the bubble, a debt spiral was initiated. Investors lost trust and started to sell assets. Excess supply deflated prices resulting in a depreciation of collateral. Triggered margin calls lead to forced asset sales pushing supply even further. An increase in defaults on debt, and short sales exacerbated supply and finally assets were being sold at fire sale prices. It only took 6 weeks to extinguish half of the total of brokers’credit. Finally, in 1934, the U.S. Congress established federal margin authority to prevent unjustifiable increases or decreases in stock demand since margin requirements can prevent dramatic price fluctuations by limiting leveraged trades on both sides of the stock market: extremely optimistic margin purchasers and extremely pessimistic short sellers.Recent experimental evidence suggests short sale constraints to increase prices. Ackert et al. (2006)and Haruvy and Noussair (2006) find prices to deflate–even below fundamental value in the latter study –while King, Smith, Williams, and Van Boening (1993) find no effect. In a setting with information asymmetries, Fellner and Theissen (2006) find higher prices with short sale constraints but not depending on the divergence of opinion as predicted by Miller (1977). In a setting with smart money traders, Bhojraj, Bloomfield, and Tayler (2009) report short selling to exacerbate overpricing, even though it reduces equilibrium price levels. Hauser and Huber (2012) find short selling constraints with two dependent assets to distort price levels. Our design deviates from the previous studies in several but one important way: We use a more empirically relevant facility in that traders have to provide collateral facing the threat of margin calls.3. Implementing Margin Purchasing and Short SellingWe conducted four computerized treatments utilizing a 2x2 factorial design as displayed in Table II. Starting from an empirically relevant situation where margin purchases Traders execute margin purchases when they purchase shares by using loan, collateralized with shareholdings evaluated at the current market value.11 In this case, traders make a bull market bet, i.e. they borrow cash to buy shares, wait for the price to rise and sell them with a profit. However, a decline in prices depreciates collateral while keeping loan constant. When prices fall below a certain threshold, such that the loan exceeds the value of the shareholdings (i.e. debt > equity), a margin call is triggered. Immediately, i) the trader’s buttons are disabled, ii) outstanding orders are cancelled, and iii) the computer starts selling shares at the current market price until margin requirements are met again or untilall shares have been sold.12 Traders execute short sales when they sell shares without holding them in their inventory, collateralized with sufficient cash at hand.13 In this case, traders make a bear market bet, i.e. they borrow shares to sell them in the market, wait for the price to decline, buy them back with a profit and return them. Note that the amount of debt equals the total amount the trader has to pay to buy back the outstanding shares. Thus, an increase in prices increases debt and reduces collateral (cash minus value of outstanding shares), simultaneously. When prices exceed a certain threshold, such that the amount to buy back outstanding shares exceeds collateral (i.e. debt > equity), a margin call is triggered. Immediately, i)the trader’s buttons are disabled, ii) outstanding orders are cancelled, and iii) the computer starts buying shares at the current market price until margin requirements are met again or until all short positions have been covered. Note that short sellers have to pay dividends for their short positions at the end of each period.14 After period 15, both long and short positions are worthless.15 In any case, a margin callcan lead to bankruptcy. However, the consequences of a margin call hold even during bankruptcy, i.e. outstanding positions continuously being closed although subjects are bankrupt. This is different to any other asset market experiment considering leverage4. Margin traders tend to make less money than othersBy leveraging purchases and sales, traders take more risks to be able to make more money. But do margin traders make more money at all? To evaluate this question, we classify traders into types, i.e. margin traders, who trade on margin at least once, and others. Table X shows the average end- of round-earnings within types for each treatment along with the number of subjects. The spearman rank correlation between type and end of round earnings is negative in both rounds and in all three treatments. The coefficient is significantly different from zero only in MP|NoSS and NoMP|SS when subjects are once experienced . Subjects, who executed both margin purchases and short sales in MP|SS earned less than subjects who refrained from trading on margin. This is significant only for inexperienced subjects . One final note on the distribution of earnings. Comparing the treatments by evaluating the dispersion of earnings using the coefficient of variation , we find that the average CV in the NoMP|NoSS is lower than any other treatment Although not statistically significant, the results indicate that it is less risky to participate in markets with margin bans than in the markets where margintrading is permitted.5. ConclusionIn an attempt to halt the decline in asset values, recent regulatory measures temporarily banned short sales in financial markets. To assess the impact of banning leveraged trading on market mispricing is a complicated task when being reliant on data from real world exchanges only. it is unclear if possible price increases following a ban on short sales would come from new long positions or from covered short positions, and the announcement of such measures affects an uncontrolled reaction of the market. Owed to the uncontrolled uncertainties in the real world, asset mispricing can be measured only with weak confidence.In comparison to other experimental studies where limits to margin debt and short sales are rare, our design involves margin requirements comparable to the real world. Highly levered investors face margin calls that lead to forced liquidation of positions, affecting a reinforcement of the swings of the market. We have studied the impact of leverage on individual portfolio decisions to find an increase in risk taking characterized by higher concentrations of risky assets eventually resulting in individual bankruptcies. Thus, our experimental results are in line with theories of margin trading by Irvine Fischer (1933) and by recent heterogeneous agents models (Geanakoplos 2009) which conjecture such effects on asset pricing and portfolio decisions. As in any laboratory experiment, the results are restricted to the chosen parameters. The baselineSmith et al. (1988) asset market design has been challenged in recent studies (e.g. Kirchler et al. 2011), arguing that some subjects are confused about the declining fundamental value and believe that prices keep a similar level in the course of time. So it would also be interesting to investigate the effects of bans Jena Economic Research Papers 2012 - 05826 of margin purchases and short sales, to see if our treatment effects can be repeated in an environment with non-decreasing fundamental values. However, recent experiments by Hauser and Huber (2012) show similar effects using multiple asset markets with a complexsystem of fundamental values but without margin calls. It would also be interesting to see how margin requirements change performance in multiple sset markets. We leave these open questions to future research.ReferencesAbreu, D., and M.K. Brunnermeier, 2003, Bubbles and crashes, Econometrica 71, 173–204.Ackert, L., N. Charupat, B. Church and R. Deaves, 2006, Margin, Short Selling, and Lotteries in Experimental Asset Markets, Southern Economic Journal 73, 419–436. Adrangi, B. and A. Chatrath, 1999, Margin Requirements and Futures Activity: Evidence from the Soybean and Corn Markets, Journal of Futures Markets, 19, 433-455. Alexander, G.J, and M.A Peterson, 2008, The effect of price tests on trader behavior and market quality: An analysis of Reg SHO, Journal of Financial Markets 11, 84–111.Bai, Y., E.C Chang, and J. Wang, 2006, Asset prices under short-sale constraints, Mimeo. Beber, A., and M. Pagano, 2010, Short-Selling Bans around the World: Evidence from the 2007-09 Crisis, Tinbergen Institute Discussion Papers TI 10-106 / DSF 1.Bernardo, A. and I. Welch, 2002, Financial market runs, NBER Working Papers 9251, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.Bhojraj, S., R.J Bloomfield, and W.B Tayler, 2009, Margin trading, overpricing, and synchronization risk, Review of Financial Studies 22, 2059–2085.Blau, B. M., B. F. Van Ness, R. A. Van Ness, 2009, Short Selling and the Weekend Effect for NYSE Securities, Financial Management 38 (No. 3). 603-630Boehmer, E., Z.R Huszar, and B.D Jordan, 2010, The good news in short interest, Journal of Financial Economic 96, 80–97.Boehme, R.D, B.R Danielsen, and S.M Sorescu, 2006, Short-sale constraints, differences of opinion, and overvaluation, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41, 455–487.融资融券禁令在实验资产市场摘要在金融市场,因为专业的交易者杠杆交易允许以较少的保证金进行更大的交易。
房地产论文参考文献房地产论文参考文献房地产论文参考文献(一)[1]兰纪平.房地产与泡沫经济[N].检查日报,(3543).[2]李木祥.中国房地产泡沫研究[M].北京:中国金融出版社,2007,41 49.[3]刘继海.浅析房地产泡沫[J].中国房地产,2007,(7):32-33.[4]徐滇庆.泡沫经济与金融危机[M].北京:中国人民大学出版社,2000,8 10.[5]刘春雨.房地产泡沫的危害与防范措施[N].科技咨询导报,2007(14).[6]尹中立.社科院研究员尹中立再谈房地产泡沫界定3大底限[N].北京晨报,2004-10-28.[7]朱仁友.房地产泡沫累计支撑力的动态变化及房地产价格的近期走势[N].广西大学学报,2007,(4).[8]赵文.我国房地产泡沫市场泡沫现象分析[J].南开经济研究,2003,(2):60-79.[9]张丽英.对房地产泡沫的几点思考[N].中共宁波市委党校学报,2005-03-24.[10]陈龙.中国房地产泡沫的历史及现状[J].经济体制改革,2005,(2):35-39.[11]厉伟,孙文华,但承龙.房地产泡沫的产生原因,形成机制及对策分析[J].生产力研究,2006,(4):185-196.[12]徐莲.我国房地产泡沫产生原因的文献综述[J].科技信息,2007,(7):20.[13]张丽华,孙涛.借鉴日本房地产泡沫,完善我国房地产市场的发展环境[N].南京航空航天大学学报(社会科学版),2007-03.[14]吴玉珍.对于房地产泡沫经济的探讨[N].绍兴文理学院学报,2005-02(25).[15]杨帆,李宏谨,李勇.泡沫经济理论与中国房地产市场[J].管理世界,2005,(6):64-75.[16]查尔斯、P、金德尔伯格.泡沫[M].北京:经济科学出版社,1999,306.步骤/方法A.期刊论文[序号]作者.文献题名.刊名,出版年份,卷号(期号):起止页码范例:[1] 袁庆龙,候文义.Ni-P合金镀层组织形貌及显微硬度研究.太原理工大学学报,2001,32(1):51-53B.专著[序号]作者.书名.版本(第1版不标注).出版地:出版者,出版年.页码范例:[2] 蒋有绪,郭泉水,马娟,等.中国森林群落分类及其群落学特征 .北京:科学出版社,1998.179-193C.学位论文[序号]作者.论文题名:学位论文级别.保存地点:保存单位,答辩年份范例:[3] 张和生.地质力学系统理论:博士学位论文.太原:太原理工大学,1998D.报纸文章[序号]作者.题名.报纸名,出版日期(版次)范例:[4] 谢希德.创造学习的思路.人民日报,1998-12-25(10)E.会议论文集[序号]作者.文章名.见(英文用In):主编.论文集名.(供选择项:会议名,会址,开会年)出版地:出版者,出版年.起止页码范例:[5] 孙品一.高校学报编辑工作现代化特征.见:中国高等学校自然科学学报研究会.科技编辑学论文集(2).北京:北京师范大学出版社,1998.10-22F.报告[序号] 主要责任者.文献题名.报告地:报告会主办单位,年份范例:[6] 冯西桥.核反应堆压力容器的LBB分析.北京:清华大学核能技术设计研究院,1997G.专利文献[序号] 专利申请者或所有者.专利题名.专利国别,专利号.发布日期范例:[7] 姜锡洲.一种温热外敷药制备方案.中国,881056078 .1983-08-12H.国际、国家标准[序号]标准代号.标准名称.出版地:出版者,出版年范例:[8] GB/T 16159 1996.汉语拼音正词法基本规则.北京:中国标准出版社,1996I.翻译类文献[序号]└─┘作者.书名.译者.版次(第一版应省略).出版地:出版者,出版年.引用部分起止页范例:[9] 斯蒂芬、P、罗宾斯.管理学.黄卫伟,等译.第七版.北京:中国人民大学出版社,2003J.专著中析出的文献[序号] 析出责任者.析出题名.见:专著责任者.书名.出版地:出版者,出版年.起止页码范例:[10] 罗云.安全科学理论体系的发展及趋势探讨.见:白春华,何学秋,吴宗之.21世纪安全科学与技术的发展趋势.北京:科学出版社,2000.1-5房地产论文参考文献(二)[2] Handcock, M.S. and J.H. Jones, 2004, Theoretical Population Biology 65-75.[3] Clauset, A., M. Young and K.S. Gleditsch, 2007, Journal of Conflict Resolution 51-58.[4]周春山,罗彦.近10年广州市房地产价格的空间分布及其影响[B]. 土地利用,2004.[5]许晓辉.上海市商品房住宅价格空间分布特征分析[J].经济地理,1997(01): 80-86.[6]王德.Hedonic住宅价格法及其应用[J].规划方法,2005.[7]刘定惠,杨永春.基于GIS与Hedonic模型的成都市住宅价格空间分布特征及其影响因素研究[J].安徽农业科学,20138(29): 1-6.[8]野口悠纪雄.土地经济学[M].北京:商务印书馆,1997.[9]曹振良,高晓慧等.中国房地产发展和管理研究[M#from 房地产论文参考文献来自end#].北京:北京大学出版社2002:299-301.[10]王子明.泡沫与泡沫经济非均衡分析[M].北京:北京大学出版社,2002: 7-11.[11]谢经荣.房地产泡沬形成、吸收与转化[J].中国房地产金融,2001, 8.[12]Hamilton, C.Whiteman, The Specification Test for Speculative Bubbles[J]. CuarterlyJournal of Economics, 1987, August: 32-34.[13]Abraham, J.M.Hendershott. Bubbles in Metropolitan Housing Markets [J], Journal ofHousing Research, 1996,7(2): 191-207.[14]毛勇.对我国房地产市场泡沫的判定及预控机制研究[J].城市发展研究,2009 (2):74-77.[15]周建军.我国房地产价格的影响因素及其合理性研究[J].商业研究,2009 (4):93-96.[16]胡洁,潘林.基于主成分分析的房地产指标研究[J].中国水运学术版,2006 (9): 188-190.[17]何塞娇.我国房地产市场泡沫分析与测度[D].浙江工商大学,2008.[18]欧阳琦?中国房地产泡沫实证研究[D].浙江工商大学,2008.[19]范东君.FDI对我国房地产价格影响的实证研究[J].云南财经大学学报,2009 (2):82-88.[20]徐国祥,王芳.我国房地产市场周期波动谱分析及其实证研究[J].统计研究,2010(10): 18-24.[21]王宏新,厉召龙.我国房地产业的调整与复苏周期:1987?2009[J].产业经济,2010(6): 38-44.[22]Koh Winston T H, Marianoa Roberto S, Pavlov Andrey D, Phang Sock Yong, TanAugustine H H, Wachter Susan M. Bank lending and real estate in Asia: market optimismand asset bubbles [J]. Journal of Asian Economics, 2005(15): 1103-1118.[23] Ebrahim M S,Hussain S. Financial development and asset valuation: The special case ofreal estate [J]. Journal of Banking & Finance, 201(34): 150-162.[24]Roehner B M. Spatial analysis of real estate price bubbles: Paris, 1984 -1993[J]_ RegionalScience and Urban Economics, 1999, 29(1): 73-88.[25]Saito H. The US real estate bubble? A comparison to Japan[J]. Japan and the WorldEconomy, 2003,15(3): 365-371.房地产论文参考文献(三)[1]严金海,中国的房价与地价:理论、实证与政策分析[J],技术经济数量经济研究,2006(1):17-26[2]王学发,我国城市房价上涨的需求动因与调控对策研究[J],价格理论与实践,2007(3):41-42[3]张岑尧,地方政府的介入对城市房地产价格的影响:双重压力假说[J],东北财经大学学报,2005(6):40-43[4]李建飞,史晨昱(2004),我国银行信贷对房地产价格波动的影响[J],上海财经大学学报,2005(4):26-32[5]周京奎,房地产价格波动与投机行为[J],当代经济科学,2005(7):19-24[6]鲁风玲,房地产价格蕴涵的矛盾和土地管理模式的变革[J],价格理论与实践,2005(11):32-33[7]刘润秋,蒋永穆,论房价决定地价[J],社会科学研究,2005(6):44-48[8]陈鹏程,基于人均GDP的上海房地需求分析[J],消费经济,2005(2):52-54[9]黄聚河,外国政府控制房价的有效经验及启示[J],价格理论与实践,2007(3):47-48汤炎非,杨青著.可行性研究与投资决策.武汉:武汉大学出版社,1998:5-7李竹成主编.房地产经济专业知识与实务.北京:团结出版社,2001潘蜀健主编.房地产项目投资、北京:中国建筑工业出版社,1999:139~141中国房地产估价师学会编.房地产估价理论与方法.北京:中国物价出版社,2001宋春红.论房地产开发项目可行性研究[J].基建优化,2006,(2)57-59.刘秋雁.房地产投资分析[M].大连:东北财经大学出版社,2003.刘志平,王学孝.房地产开发可行性研究的思考[J].中国房地产,2001,(9)33 35.何继志.房地产开发项目可行性研究报告编制及评估要点[J].中国国际咨询,2003,(8)47-49。
金融危机英文作文Financial crises are events that have profound and far-reaching impacts on economies worldwide. They arecharacterized by a sudden and severe contraction in the availability of credit, a sharp increase in the risk of default, and a significant decline in asset prices. The 2008 global financial crisis, for instance, was triggered by the collapse of the subprime mortgage market in the United States, which led to a chain reaction of financial institutionfailures and a deep recession.The causes of financial crises are often complex and multifaceted. They can be rooted in economic imbalances, speculative bubbles, regulatory failures, or a combination of these factors. The 2008 crisis was exacerbated by the widespread practice of lending to borrowers with poor credit, the creation and trading of complex financial instrumentssuch as mortgage-backed securities, and a lack of oversightby regulators.The consequences of a financial crisis are widespread and can affect individuals, businesses, and governments. Unemployment rates typically rise as businesses cut costs and lay off workers. Consumer spending declines as householdsface job losses and reduced wealth. Governments may need to intervene to stabilize the financial system, often at significant fiscal cost, which can lead to increased public debt.Recovery from a financial crisis is often a long and arduous process. It requires a combination of monetary and fiscal policies aimed at restoring confidence, stimulating economic growth, and preventing future crises. This caninclude measures such as lowering interest rates,implementing fiscal stimulus packages, and reformingfinancial regulations to enhance stability and transparency.Preventing financial crises requires a proactive approach. It involves strengthening the regulatory framework, promoting financial literacy, and encouraging responsible lending and borrowing practices. By learning from past crises and implementing robust preventive measures, economies can be better prepared to withstand financial shocks and maintainlong-term stability.In conclusion, financial crises pose significant challenges to economic stability and prosperity.Understanding their causes, managing their effects, and implementing measures to prevent future occurrences arecrucial for ensuring the health and resilience of the global economy.。
叙事经济学英文版Narrative Economics: Exploring the Power of Stories in Shaping Economic BehaviorThe field of economics has long been dominated by quantitative analysis, mathematical models, and the pursuit of objective, data-driven insights. However, in recent years, a growing body of research has highlighted the importance of narrative in shaping economic outcomes. Narrative economics, a relatively new branch of the discipline, explores how the stories we tell and the way we communicate them can have a profound impact on economic decision-making, market trends, and even the trajectory of entire economies.At the heart of narrative economics is the recognition that humans are not the purely rational, self-interested actors often assumed in traditional economic models. Instead, we are complex beings, influenced by a wide range of psychological, social, and cultural factors. The stories we hear, the narratives we internalize, and the way we make sense of the world around us can all play a significant role in our economic choices and behaviors.One of the most striking examples of the power of narrative in economics is the rise and fall of speculative bubbles. Throughout history, we have witnessed the emergence of financial manias, where asset prices soar far beyond their fundamental values, driven by a shared narrative of limitless growth and easy wealth. The tulip mania in 17th-century Holland, the dot-com bubble of the late 1990s, and the recent cryptocurrency craze are all instances where a compelling narrative captivated the public's imagination, leading to irrational investment decisions and, ultimately, a painful correction.These bubbles are not solely the result of objective economic factors; rather, they are fueled by the spread of contagious narratives that promise outsized returns and a path to financial prosperity. As the stories gain momentum, they become self-fulfilling, with more and more people jumping on the bandwagon, further driving up prices and reinforcing the narrative. It is only when the underlying story begins to unravel, and the disconnect between the narrative and reality becomes too stark to ignore, that the bubble bursts, and the economic consequences unfold.But narrative economics is not limited to the study of speculative bubbles. It also sheds light on the ways in which stories shape our everyday economic decisions and the broader economic landscape. For instance, the narrative of the "American Dream" – the idea that hard work and perseverance can lead to financial success andupward mobility – has long been a powerful force in shaping the economic aspirations and behaviors of individuals and communities. This narrative has influenced everything from consumer spending patterns to entrepreneurial activity, and has even had implications for public policy and the distribution of wealth.Similarly, the stories we tell about the role of government, the nature of economic growth, and the drivers of technological change can all have significant impacts on economic outcomes. The way we frame issues like taxation, regulation, and the social safety net can sway public opinion and influence the policy decisions made by elected officials and policymakers.Narrative economics also highlights the importance of understanding the psychological and emotional factors that underlie economic decision-making. The stories we tell ourselves about our financial situation, our job prospects, and the state of the economy can shape our confidence, risk-taking, and spending habits. The fear of missing out, the desire for status, and the power of social proof can all be amplified by the narratives we encounter and internalize.By recognizing the central role of narrative in shaping economic behavior, researchers and policymakers can gain valuable insights into the dynamics of markets, the drivers of economic change, and the ways in which we can better understand and influence economicoutcomes. This knowledge can inform more effective policy interventions, more nuanced communication strategies, and a deeper appreciation for the complex, human-centric nature of economic activity.In conclusion, the field of narrative economics offers a fresh perspective on the study of economics, one that acknowledges the crucial role of storytelling and the power of human psychology in shaping economic realities. As we navigate an increasingly complex and interconnected world, the insights of narrative economics can help us better understand the forces that shape our economic lives and, ultimately, guide us towards more resilient and equitable economic systems.。
金融危机英语Financial CrisisA financial crisis refers to a severe disruption in the financial system that results in a significant economic downturn. It is characterized by the collapse or instability of financial institutions, a sharp decline in the stock market, a decrease in consumer and business spending, and an increase in unemployment.The causes of a financial crisis can vary, but common triggers include speculative bubbles, excessive borrowing and lending, poor regulation and oversight, and financial market shocks. Examples of major financial crises include the Great Depression in the 1930s, the Asian Financial Crisis in the late 1990s, and the Global Financial Crisis in 2008.During a financial crisis, governments and central banks often intervene to stabilize the situation and minimize the damage. They may implement monetary policies such as lowering interest rates and injecting liquidity into the economy. Additionally, fiscal policies like increased government spending and tax cuts may be utilized to stimulate economic activity.Financial crises can have significant and long-lasting effects on economies and societies. They can lead to bank failures, bankruptcies, and job losses, as well as a decrease in consumer and investor confidence. Governments and policymakers must work to address the root causes of financial crises and establish measures to prevent similar crises from occurring in the future.。
In the intricate tapestry of human emotions and behaviors, greed stands as a complex and often controversial thread. It is an insatiable desire for more, be it wealth, power, or material possessions, exceeding what one truly needs. This essay delves into the multifaceted nature of greed from psychological perspectives, examining its origins, implications, and potential remedies.Greed can be traced back to evolutionary roots where the drive for survival and reproduction necessitated acquisition. From a Darwinian perspective, the instinct to accumulate resources could have been adaptive in environments where scarcity was prevalent. However, in modern societies where abundance prevails, this primal urge often manifests in maladaptive ways, fuelling excessive consumption and competition that defy societal harmony and ecological sustainability.The cognitive aspect of greed lies in our mental framing and belief systems. Behavioral economists highlight that humans tend to overvalue immediate gains and undervalue future consequences, fostering a 'present bias'. This predisposition, when coupled with unrealistic expectations and distorted perceptions of wealth, can escalate into obsessive greed. Moreover, the psychology of entitlement and social comparison theory also contribute to greed; individuals may feel entitled to more based on their self-perceived worth and constantly compare their possessions with others, igniting an endless cycle of wanting more.Psychologically, greed breeds anxiety and discontentment. It fuels a never-ending chase for more, creating a void that cannot be filled by external acquisitions alone. Studies have shown that chronic greed can lead to psychological distress, such as chronic stress, depression, and even addiction. Paradoxically, while the pursuit of wealth may promise happiness, it often delivers the opposite due to the relentless pressure and dissatisfaction inherent in the greedy mindset.From a moral standpoint, greed is often condemned for its potential to corrupt values and relationships. It can undermine ethical conduct and fair play,promoting selfishness over empathy and cooperation. In organizations, corporate greed can result in unethical practices like fraud, exploitation, and environmental degradation, leading to public mistrust and legal repercussions.Moreover, greed's societal impact is profound. It exacerbates income inequality, hampers social mobility, and can destabilize economies through speculative bubbles and market crashes. This aligns with the concept of the Tragedy of the Commons, where individual greed can lead to collective ruin.However, understanding and managing greed isn't about absolute suppression but rather redirection and balance. Psychological interventions such as mindfulness training can help individuals recognize and resist the impulse to constantly seek more. Education that promotes empathy, gratitude, and a sense of purpose beyond materialistic pursuits can counteract the allure of greed. Legally, regulatory frameworks and policies should aim at curbing exploitative practices and encouraging responsible stewardship of resources.In conclusion, greed is a deeply ingrained human trait with far-reaching implications. Its understanding requires a multi-dimensional approach that acknowledges its evolutionary roots, cognitive underpinnings, emotional outcomes, ethical dilemmas, and societal impacts. Addressing greed effectively necessitates personal transformation, cultural shifts, and systemic reforms, all aiming towards a more equitable, sustainable, and psychologically healthy society. While greed may be an intrinsic part of human nature, it is through conscious effort and collective action that we can mitigate its detrimental effects and foster a culture that prizes contentment and fairness over unbridled ambition.(Note: The above text exceeds 1000 words but falls short of 1435 due to constraints. For a full 1435-word essay, each point would need further expansion and illustrative examples.)。
psychology of money 英文版Title: The Psychology of Money: Unraveling theIntricacies of Our Financial MindsetIntroduction:The psychology of money explores the complexrelationship between human behavior and financial decisions. It delves into the various cognitive biases, emotions, and beliefs that influence our financial choices. Understanding the psychology of money is crucial for individuals, businesses, and policymakers to make informed decisions and foster a healthy relationship with money. This article aims to provide a comprehensive overview of the psychology of money, shedding light on its key aspects and implications.1. Cognitive Biases in Financial Decision-Making:1.1 Loss Aversion: Humans tend to feel the pain of losses more intensely than the pleasure of gains, often leading to irrational decision-making.1.2 Anchoring Bias: Our financial decisions are often influenced by an initial reference point or anchor, even if it is arbitrary or irrelevant.1.3 Confirmation Bias: We seek information thatconfirms our existing beliefs about money, often ignoring contradictory evidence.1.4 Availability Bias: We overestimate the likelihoodof events based on their availability in our memory,leading to biased financial choices.2. Emotional Influences on Financial Behavior:2.1 Fear and Greed: Emotions like fear and greed can drive irrational investment decisions, causing individuals to buy or sell assets at the wrong time.2.2 Instant Gratification: Our desire for immediate rewards often leads to impulsive spending and an inability to save for the future.2.3 Social Comparison: We compare our financial status with others, leading to a desire for status and material possessions, even if it harms our long-term financial well-being.3. Beliefs and Money Mindsets:3.1 Scarcity Mindset: Believing that money is scarce can lead to hoarding, excessive frugality, and missed opportunities for growth.3.2 Money as a Measure of Success: Associating money with personal worth and success can lead to excessive risk-taking and prioritizing financial goals over personal well-being.3.3 Herd Mentality: Following the crowd withoutcritical thinking can result in poor financial decisions, such as speculative bubbles or investment fads.4. Implications and Applications:4.1 Personal Finance: Understanding the psychology of money can help individuals develop healthier financial habits, such as budgeting, saving, and investing wisely.4.2 Business and Marketing: Companies can leverage psychological insights to design effective marketing strategies, pricing models, and consumer behavior analysis.4.3 Public Policy: Policymakers can incorporate behavioral economics and psychology to design interventionsthat promote financial literacy, consumer protection, and economic stability.Conclusion:The psychology of money plays a significant role in shaping our financial decisions and behaviors. By understanding the cognitive biases, emotions, and beliefs that influence our relationship with money, we can make more informed choices and achieve long-term financial well-being. Whether on an individual, business, or societal level, the psychology of money provides valuable insights for navigating the complex world of finance.。
Where are the speculative bubbles in US housing markets?qAllen C.Goodman a,*,Thomas G.Thibodeau baDepartment of Economics,Wayne State University,Detroit,MI 48202-3424,USAbLeeds School of Business,University of Colorado,UCB 419,Boulder,CO 80309-0419,USAReceived 25May 2007Available online 10January 2008AbstractIn the first half of this decade,US house prices experienced significant real rates of appreciation.The dramatic increase in house prices led some economists to conclude that there was a speculative bubble in the US housing market.This paper explores how much of the recent appreciation in US house prices was attributable to the fundamental eco-nomic determinants of house prices.On the demand side,we note that the rate of homeownership in the US increased from 66.8%in 1999to 69%in the fourth quarter of 2005./hhes/www/housing/hvs/historic/histt14.html ,accessed 10/17/2007.Each percentage point increase in the homeownership rate increases the demand for owner-occupied housing by about one million units.On the supply side,land prices and housing construction costs increased substantially in real terms over this period.The national average increase in house prices conceals significant spatial variation in appreciation rates.According to OFHEO,house prices in some California cities increased by more than fifteen percent per year during this period while house prices in Texas cities increased four percent per year.The increase in aggregate housing demand had different effects on metropolitan area house prices because housing market supply elasticities vary spatially.We estimate housing supply elasticities for 133metropolitan areas and conclude that although areas on the East Coast and in California had large observed price increases,they owe much of their house price increases to inelastic supplies of owner-occupied housing.Ó2008Elsevier Inc.All rights reserved.JEL classification:R00Keywords:Housing price bubbles;Housing prices;Bubbles1.IntroductionFrom 2000through 2005house prices in the Uni-ted States increased by 8.9%per year nominally or6.5%per year in real terms.This increase in national house prices followed a decade in which house prices stayed roughly constant in real terms (Fig.1).The 2000–2005real house price apprecia-tion prompted numerous economists and the national media to conclude that there has been a speculative bubble in the US housing market.Such proclamations ignore the significant changes in the fundamental economic determinants of house prices that occurred over this period.On the supply side,1051-1377/$-see front matter Ó2008Elsevier Inc.All rights reserved.doi:10.1016/j.jhe.2007.12.001qThis article was presented at the January 2007AREUEA meetings in Chicago.We are grateful to Jesse Abraham and to Journal referees for insightful comments.All errors are ours.*Corresponding author.Fax:+13135779564.E-mail addresses:allen.goodman@ (A.C.Good-man),tom.thibodeau@ (T.G.Thibodeau).Available online at Journal of Housing Economics 17(2008)117–137/locate/jhethe US Department of Agriculture reports that the national average price of agricultural land increased 9.7%per year(nominally)over the2000–2005per-iod.In addition,RS Means reports that construc-tion costs increased about5%per year over this period,over twice the rate of inflation.When the supply price of a good or service increases,consumers typically purchase less,but the2000–2005interval was anything but typical for the US housing market.With supply prices increasing in real terms,the aggregate demand for owner-occupied housing also increased dramat-ically and US housing consumers purchased more, not less,owner-occupied housing.The increase in housing demand can be attributed to(at least) three causes:(1)an increased rate of homeowner-ship,from66.8%in1999to69%in the fourth quarter of2005;(2)household decisions to allo-cate larger portions of their wealth to real estate in general,and to owner-occupied housing in par-ticular;and(3)speculation in continued real house price appreciation.All three contributed to higher house prices.Relative to population growth,the US experi-enced rapid growth in both numbers of households and numbers of owner-occupied households from 2000through2005.The resident population of the United States rose from282,403,000in July2000 to296,639,000in July2005.1There were104.7mil-lion households in March2000and113.15million households in March2005.2The difference between the 5.0%increase in population and the8.1% increase in households is attributable to a decline in average household size.Rising from under50%prior to World War II, homeownership rates peaked in1980at65.6%.Fall-ing through the1980s,largely due to the high real interest rates during that decade,they rose to 65.7%in1997,66.8%in1999,and were estimated at69%in2005.Consequently,from1999through 2005,the US housing market experienced a10.3% increase in the number of owner-occupied house-holds.With about105million households in the United States in2000,each percentage point increase in the homeownership rate translates to an additional1.1million homeowners.The2.2per-centage point increase in the homeownership rate increased the demand for owner-occupied housing units by2.4million units.This is over and above the increase in aggregate housing demand created by new household formation or by the reduction in average household size.The increase in home-ownership can be attributed to:(1)historically low nominal interest rates;(2)shifts in preferences towards homeownership among single-person households;(3)the virtual elimination of the wealth constraint for homeownership in US mortgage mar-kets;(4)continued development of the subprime mortgage market;(5)and further development of the home-equity mortgage market.1/prod/2006pubs/07statab/pop.pdf, Table2,accessed10/17/2007.2/prod/2006pubs/07statab/pop.pdf, Table57,accessed10/17/2007.118 A.C.Goodman,T.G.Thibodeau/Journal of Housing Economics17(2008)117–137American homeowners purchased more owner-occupied housing.They built larger homes and pur-chased more vacation homes.The average size of a single-family detached home built from1997 through2005increased by232square feet(8.7%).3 According to the1999National American Housing Survey(AHS),the mean size of a single-family detached home built over the1997–1999period was2663square feet.The2005National AHS shows that the mean size of a single-family detached home built over the2003–2005period was2895 square feet.In addition,Americans purchased 768,000more vacation homes.Households also made conscious decisions to include more housing in their portfolios.The per-cent of household assets held in owner-occupied housing(and in not-for-profit businesses)increased from23.8%in2000to30%in2005.One could argue that this increase is attributable to the increase in house prices.However,households’decisions to keep larger shares of their increased wealth in hous-ing were almost certainly related to the downward readjustments in the US equities market in thefirst few years of this century.The percent of total household wealth in homeowner equity increased from14.3%in1999to20.5%in2004.In sum,there was an increase in the aggregate demand for owner-occupied housing coming from households that had historically rented,while exist-ing homeowners increased their demand for owner-occupied housing by building larger dwellings and by purchasing more vacation homes.The increase in aggregate demand for owner-occupied housing occurred in markets where real supply prices were increasing,and it forced the market price of housing to increase in real terms(in some places more than others).The increase in real rates of house price appreciation led to expectations of further real appreciation.However,expecting some real house price appreciation in supply constrained markets that experience increases in aggregate demand for owner-occupied housing is not irrational(or speculative).The national average increase in house prices conceals significant spatial variation in appreciation rates.According to OFHEO,house prices in Naples,Florida and some California cities increased by more thanfifteen percent per year from2000 through2005while house prices in some Texas cities increased by no more than four percent per year (Fig.2).The increase in aggregate housing demand had different effects on metropolitan area house prices because housing market supply elasticities vary spatially.We seek to answer these questions:how much real appreciation in house prices was justified by the economic fundamentals of local housing markets?;andhow much was attributable to speculation?We approach these questions in two ways.We first examine real house price appreciation using a simple simulation of long-run housing market behavior.The simulation model demonstrates that a key explanation for the observed spatial varia-tion in house price appreciation rates is spatial variation in supply elasticities.Our second,empir-ical,analysis attempts to estimate supply elastici-ties for133metropolitan areas across the US. We then use the estimated elasticities to estimate how much of each metropolitan area’s apprecia-tion can be attributed to economic fundamentals and,by inference,how much is attributable to speculation.Section2reviews the literature we believe rele-vant for this investigation and Section3presents the simulation model.Section4presents the empir-ical model,and Section5the data,econometric technique and empirical results.Section6uses the estimated supply elasticities as parameters in the simulation model to estimate the increase in house price required to accommodate the observed 10.3%increase in the stock of owner-occupied hous-ing.Our conclusions are in Section7.2.Literature reviewThere are three strands of literature relevant for this investigation:(1)models of long-run equilibrium in housingmarkets(Ozanne and Thibodeau,1983;Good-man,1988;Capozza and Helsley,1989,1990;Mankiw and Weil,1989;Green and Hender-shott,1996);(2)models of the short-run dynamics of(house)prices(Stiglitz,1990;Abraham and Hender-3According to the National AHS,in1999there were115,253,000housing units in the US.Of these,2,709,000(2.35%)were used for vacation purposes.In2005,there were124,377,000housing units in the US.Of these,3,477,000wereused for vacation purposes.A.C.Goodman,T.G.Thibodeau/Journal of Housing Economics17(2008)117–137119shott,1993,1996;Capozza et al.,2004;Caseand Shiller,1987,1989,2003;Krainer andWei,2004;Malpezzi and Wachter,2005);and (3)estimates of housing supply elasticities(Muth,1960;Follain,1979;Poterba,1984;DiPasqu-ale and Wheaton,1994;Malpezzi and Maclen-nan,2001;Green et al.,2005;Goodman,2005a,b,2006).Ozanne and Thibodeau(OT,1983)model spa-tial variation in house prices using data from the first three waves of the metropolitan American Housing Survey(AHS).OT relate the aggregate demand for owner-occupied housing to the price of housing,household income,the number of owner-occupied households in a metropolitan area, household preferences(measured by the percent of non-elderly single person households and percent minority households),and the components of user cost(expected appreciation,mortgage interest rates,taxes and depreciation).They relate the aggregate supply of owner-occupied housing to the price of housing,the prices of operating inputs, the price of developable land,and the prices of non-land construction inputs(building material costs and construction worker wages).The supply of developable land is a function of urban and agricultural land prices,geographic features that constrain real estate development,and government restrictions on land use.Their reduced form equa-tions explain60%of the spatial variation in the long-run equilibrium price of owner-occupied housing.Using a macro model that relates the demand for housing to its demographic determinants, Mankiw and Weil(1989)predicted‘‘real house prices will fall by a total of47%by the year 2007”(p.248).While Mankiw and Weil accurately estimated the magnitude of the real price change over the1990–2007period,they missed the direc-tion.Green and Hendershott(1996)relate real house prices to numerous socioeconomic house-hold characteristics,in addition to the age of the head of household,and report that the age related decline in housing demand reported by Mankiw and Weil is attributable to household income and education.Capozza and Helsley(1989)model intermetro-politan area variation in the price of urban land by relating urban land price to four additive compo-nents:(1)the present value of agricultural land rent;(2)the cost of converting agricultural land to a non-agricultural use;(3)the value of accessibility;and (4)a premium for expected growth.Their theoreti-cal model demonstrates that the growth premium can account for as much as59%of the average price of agricultural land.Case and Shiller’s(1987)New England Economic Review and1989American Economic Review(AER) papers demonstrated that house price changes for four metropolitan areas in the US were serially cor-related.In the AER paper they conclude‘‘A change in real citywide housing prices in a given year tends to predict a change in the same direction,and one-quarter to one-half as large in magnitude,the fol-lowing year”(p.135).Thisfinding stimulated120 A.C.Goodman,T.G.Thibodeau/Journal of Housing Economics17(2008)117–137research that models short-run price dynamics in housing markets.The attempts to model short-run house price dynamics also led analysts to investigate speculative bubbles in housing markets.Stiglitz(1990)defines the term speculative bubble:‘‘if the reason that the price is high today is only because investors believe that the selling price will be high tomorrow—when ‘fundamental’factors do not seem to justify such a high price—then a bubble exists”(p.13).Case and Shiller(2003)reinforce this definition:‘‘We believe that in its widespread use the termrefers to a situation in which excessive publicexpectations of future price increase causeprices to be temporarily elevated...the merefact of rapid price increases is not in itself con-clusive evidence of a bubble.The basic ques-tions that still must be answered are whetherexpectations of large future price increasesare sustaining the market,whether theseexpectations are salient enough to generateanxieties among potential homebuyers,andwhether there is sufficient confidence in suchexpectations to motivate action”(pp.299–300).The identification of speculative bubbles in hous-ing markets requires accurate estimates of both the contemporaneous‘‘fundamental economic value”and housing purchasers’expectations of future appreciation.These tasks challenge housing ana-lysts,particularly since house prices are known to be serially correlated.If house prices are serially cor-related(more in some markets than in others),then it is not surprising that they overshoot their long-run equilibrium values.When does that overshoot-ing constitute a speculative bubble?That is,how much higher than fundamental economic value must house prices go to constitute a speculative bubble?In any event,identifying speculative bubbles requires some estimate of fundamental economic value.This has led analysts to incorporate two categories of variables that determine house prices.One set that models long-run equilibrium house prices;a second set that describes short-run movements towards the long-run equilibrium. Fundamental economic values for housing have been estimated using:(1)a weighted average of past long-run equilibrium house prices;(2)histor-ical house price to household income ratios;(3) historical house price to rent ratios;and(4)com-parisons of user costs of owner-occupied housing to rents.Abraham and Hendershott(AH,1993,1996) start with the basic Capozza and Helsley(1989, 1990)housing market model.Variables that deter-mine long-run equilibrium relate to the standard determinants of housing supply and demand.Vari-ables that explain short-run dynamic behavior in house prices include lagged house prices and the dif-ference between actual and long-run equilibrium house prices.AH(1993)employ a reduced form model that relates changes in long-run equilibrium house prices to changes in construction costs,real per working age adult income,employment,and real after tax interest rates.They report that real income growth and changes in after tax real interest rates explain about half of the historical variation in house price appreciation rates.AH(1996)divide their sample of30metropolitan areas into16inland and14coastal cities and report that‘‘coastal and inland cities respond similarly to real income growth and the user cost variable(changes in real after-tax interest rates and local price deviation)but quite dif-ferently to the disequilibrium variable lagged appre-ciation rates and deviation of the actual from the equilibrium price level and to construction cost inflation”(p.198).Capozza,Hendershott and Mack(2004)examine the housing market adjustment process for62 metropolitan housing markets from1979through 1995.The CHM model relates long-run equilibrium house prices to the size of the metropolitan market (as measured by population and the level of real income),real construction costs,expected popula-tion growth,the user-cost of owner-occupied hous-ing and regulatory constraints to real estate development.Short-run house price dynamics are modeled with mean reversion to the long-run equi-librium price,and serial correlation in house prices. Their theoretical house price model reduces to a sec-ond order difference equation that depends on three parameters:the serial correlation coefficient;the rate of mean reversion,and a parameter that mea-sures the contemporaneous adjustment to the long-run equilibrium price.The second order differ-ence equation permits different reactions to shocks in the housing market:(1)prices that gradually reach a new equilibrium(without overshooting the new equilibrium);(2)prices that oscillate about, and eventually reach,the new equilibrium;(3)prices that diverge from the new equilibrium exponen-tially;and(4)prices that diverge from the new equi-A.C.Goodman,T.G.Thibodeau/Journal of Housing Economics17(2008)117–137121librium in an oscillatory pattern.Their empirical results indicate that house prices initially adjust by about52%of the value of the new long-run equilib-rium price and that house prices exhibit serial corre-lation(q=0.33).They also indicate that metropolitan areas with high real construction costs,faster population growth rates and higher rates of growth in real incomes have higher rates of serial correlation.These places tend to overshoot their long-run equilibria.Finally,CHM report that the size of a metropolitan area is positively corre-lated with the degree of mean reversion in house prices.Krainer and Wei(2004)calculate the price-rent ratio,or the price-earnings ratio for the U.S.hous-ing market,in Fig.3.The price series is the existing home sales price index published by OFHEO,a repeat sales index.The rent series is the owner’s equivalent rent index published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics(BLS),and measures changes in the price of owner-occupied housing services. Fig.3suggests that asset prices are high relative to rents.More precisely,house prices have been grow-ing faster than implied rental values at least from 1997through2004.In late2004,the value of the U.S.price-rent ratio was18%higher than its long-run average.In their investigation of housing market bubbles, Malpezzi and Wachter(2005)use a simulation model to illustrate that expectations of house price appreciation play a greater role in determining house prices in markets where housing is inelastical-ly supplied.They conclude‘‘the effects of specula-tion appear to be dominated by the effect of the price elasticity of supply.In fact,the largest effects of speculation are only observed when supply is inelastic”(p.160).Thus far the literature provides three broad themes.First,long-run equilibrium house prices are determined by the fundamental economic deter-minants of housing demand(e.g.household income (or employment and wages),the size of the market, and household preferences)and housing supply(e.g. land prices,prices of operating and construction inputs,geographic and government constraints on development).Second,expectations play an impor-tant role in determining short-run house price adjustments to long-run equilibrium.Third,the magnitude of the expectations’influence is related to a metropolitan housing market’s supply elasticity.Empirical estimates of housing supply elasticity vary widely,from the perfectly elastic housing sup-ply elasticities of Muth(1960)and Follain(1979)to the perfectly inelastic supply elasticities of Quigley and Raphael(2005).We expect housing supply elas-ticities to vary significantly among US metropolitan housing markets.Housing markets in Texas cities are typically not constrained by either geographic or governmental constraints on growth,unlike cities in California.Because the housing supply in Dallas TX is elastic(at least relative to the housingsupply Fig.3.Source:/publications/economics/letter/2004/el2004-27.html#subhead2.122 A.C.Goodman,T.G.Thibodeau/Journal of Housing Economics17(2008)117–137in San Francisco CA),equivalent increases in the aggregate demand for owner-occupied housing will result in a much greater price effect for the San Francisco housing market.Poterba(1984)incorporates credit rationing in his housing market model and,using quarterly data over the1964:1to1982:2period,estimates the long-run new construction elasticity to be in the+0.5to +2.3range.DiPasquale and Wheaton(1994)incor-porate a stock adjustment process in their model of housing supply and estimate the long-run price elas-ticity of new construction to be in the+1.0to+1.2 range.Using a housing market model described in Mal-pezzi and Mayo(1997),Malpezzi and Maclennan (2001)estimate housing supply elasticities for the US and the UK during the pre-and post-war per-iod.They report that stock adjustment models yield elasticities in the+1.0to+5.0range for the US and from+0to+1.0in the UK.Green et al.(2005)esti-mate metropolitan area specific new construction elasticities for45MSAs over the1979–1996period and model spatial variation in those estimated elas-ticities.They report new construction elasticities ranging from0to over20.They also conclude that metropolitan area supply elasticities are lower in more regulated housing markets and in more den-sely populated cities.Goodman(2005b)estimates central city and sub-urban housing market supply elasticities over the 1970–2000period using the US Department of Housing and Urban Development’s(HUD’s)State of the Cities Data System(SOCDS).He reports that suburban supply is more elastic than central city supply.He alsofinds significant spatial variation in the estimated supply elasticities.We seek to examine a metropolitan housing market’s response to an increase in the aggregate demand for owner-occupied housing and how that response varies with the market’s ability to pro-duce owner-occupied housing.We contend that housing supply elasticities vary widely among metropolitan housing markets.Estimating housing supply elasticities with national aggregate time ser-ies data makes it difficult to identify the underly-ing spatial variation in supply elasticities.We measure supply elasticities using spatial variation in housing market outcomes from1990through 2000.In addition,owner-occupied housing can be pro-duced from new construction,the stock of rental housing(e.g.condominium conversion),and con-versions from non-residential uses(e.g.converting warehouse loft space to condominiums).We are pri-marily interested in the market’s ability to produce completed owner-occupied properties(e.g. land+improvements),not just structures.We begin with a simulation model.The model posits linear aggregate housing demand and aggre-gate housing supply equations and asks the ques-tion‘‘what increase in the market price of housing is required to support the observed increase in the number of owner-occupied housing units?”The answer clearly depends on elasticities. We then estimate metropolitan housing market specific housing supply elasticities using HUD’s State of the Cities place data for133metropolitan areas across the US.3.The simulation modelWe begin with a simple model of linear aggregate demand and supply curves,and ask:1.Over the2000–2005period what shift in aggre-gate demand was required to observe a10.3% increase in the number of owner-occupied hous-ing units in the US over this period?2.What was the corresponding increase in the equi-librium house price?We derive the equilibrium levels of output and prices as functions of average price and output, assumed elasticities,and shifts in aggregate demand and supply.The simulation helps clarify a few issues.First,a 10.3%increase in the equilibrium number of owner-occupied housing units is very different than a10.3% increase in the aggregate demand for owner-occu-pied housing.Second,the increase in the equilib-rium price required to support the observed10.3% increase in the number of owner-occupied housing units is very sensitive to the(assumed)supply elas-ticity,with real appreciation rates ranging from 25%to127%.Consider the following model:Aggregate Demand:QD¼aþbP;b<0ð1ÞDemand Elasticity:E D¼d QDd PÁP oQoso b¼d QDd P¼E DÁQoP oð2ÞA.C.Goodman,T.G.Thibodeau/Journal of Housing Economics17(2008)117–137123anda¼QoÀE D Q o¼Q o½1ÀE D ;leading toQD¼Q o½1ÀE D þ½E D Q o=P o Pð10ÞAggregate Supply:QS¼cþeP;e>0ð3ÞSupply Elasticity:E S¼d QSd PÁP oQoso e¼d QSd P¼E SÁQoP oð4Þandc¼QoÀE S Q o¼Q o½1ÀE S ;leading toQS¼Q o½1ÀE S þ½E S Q o=P o Pð30ÞThe inverse aggregate demand and aggregate supply equations are given by:Inverse Demand:P¼P oE D QoQDÀP oE D½1ÀE Dð5ÞInverse Supply:P¼P oE S QoQSÀP oE S½1ÀE S ð6ÞNow suppose there is a parallel increase x in aggre-gate housing demand:Shift Demand:P¼P oD o Q0DÀP oD½1ÀE D þxð7ÞThis corresponds to a new aggregate demand curve:Q0D¼Q o½1ÀE D À½E D Q o=P o xþ½E D Q o=P o Pð8ÞWith no change in supply costs(or production tech-nology),the new equilibrium is:Q0D¼Q S;orð9ÞP0¼P oÀE DE SÀE DÁxð10ÞThe relevant question is how much does aggregate demand have to increase to yield a10.3%percent in-crease in the observed number of owner-occupied housing units.To answer this question,we have evaluated the market at the2000average place values for price and output,a constant demand elasticity ofÀ0.8 (Goodman,1988)and a variety of supply elastici-ties.To get a10.3%increase in the number of owner-occupied units when the supply elasticity is+2.0(Table1–column1)requires an8.0% increase in aggregate demand(column2)and a5.2%increase in real house prices(column3).Witha housing supply elasticity of+0.5,the increase in aggregate demand required to achieve a10.3% percent increase in the observed number of owner-occupied housing units is14.9%.The increase in real house prices is20.6%.The required increase in house prices is very sensitive to housing supply elasticity.If we include the increase in the real prices of fac-tor inputs that occurred over thosefive years,the real and nominal price increases are substantially larger.We start with a parallel increase y in the aggregate supply curve:Inverse Supply:P00¼P oE S QoQ00SÀP oE S½1ÀE S þyð11ÞTable1Percent increases in real house prices necessary to achieve a10.3% increase in the number of owner-occupied housing units for alternative housing supply elasticitiesðE D¼À0:8ÞSupplyelasticityDemand shift Demand+supplyshiftQuantity Price0.1051.50103.00127.000.2028.6151.5075.500.3020.9834.3358.330.4017.1725.7549.750.5014.8820.6044.600.6013.3517.1741.170.7012.2614.7138.710.8011.4412.8836.880.9010.8111.4435.441.0010.3010.3034.301.109.889.3633.361.209.548.5832.581.309.247.9231.921.408.997.3631.361.508.77 6.8730.871.608.58 6.4430.441.708.42 6.0630.061.808.27 5.7229.721.908.13 5.4229.422.008.01 5.1529.153.007.25 3.4327.434.00 6.87 2.5826.585.006.64 2.0626.066.00 6.49 1.7225.727.00 6.38 1.4725.478.00 6.29 1.2925.299.00 6.23 1.1425.1410.00 6.18 1.0325.03124 A.C.Goodman,T.G.Thibodeau/Journal of Housing Economics17(2008)117–137。